throbber

`
`Case 5:20-cv-04130 Document 1 Filed 06/22/20 Page 1 of 27
`
`
`
`
`Tina Wolfson, SBN 174806
`twolfson@ahdootwolfson.com
`Theodore W. Maya, SBN 223242
`tmaya@ahdootwolfson.com
`Christopher E. Stiner, SBN 276033
`cstiner@ahdootwolfson.com
`AHDOOT & WOLFSON, PC
`10728 Lindbrook Drive
`Los Angeles, California 90024
`Telephone: (310) 474-9111
`Facsimile: (310) 474-8585
`
`Attorneys for Plaintiffs
`
`
`
`UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
`NORTHERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA
`SAN JOSE DIVISION
`
`
`
`MICHAEL DEVANEY, NICHOLAS
`ARRIETA, and SARA YBERRA,
`individually and on behalf of all others
`similarly situated,
`
` Plaintiffs,
` v.
`
`GOOGLE LLC and ALPHABET INC.,
`
` Defendants.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Case No. 5:20-cv-04130
`
`
`CLASS ACTION COMPLAINT
`
`
`
`
`DEMAND FOR JURY TRIAL
`
`
`
`
`
`CLASS ACTION COMPLAINT, CASE NO. 5:20-cv-04130
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`29
`30
`31
`
`
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`Case 5:20-cv-04130 Document 1 Filed 06/22/20 Page 2 of 27
`
`
`
`Plaintiffs Michael Devaney, Nicholas Arrieta, and Sara Yberra (collectively,
`“Plaintiffs”), acting individually and on behalf of all others similarly situated, bring this
`action for damages and equitable relief under the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 2, and the
`Unfair Competition Law, Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code § 17200 et seq. against Defendants
`Google LLC and Alphabet Inc. (collectively, “Google”).
`NATURE OF THE CASE
`1.
`Google has achieved an illegal monopoly by eliminating competition in
`digital display advertising. Specifically, Google gained dominance in the display
`advertising ad tech stack through acquisition of competitors, exclusivity provisions,
`interoperability/compatibility design choices, and development of its analytics services.
`With its ability to track millions of users across millions of sites and apps, other
`publishers cannot compete with Google’s informational advantage.
`2.
`Google’s market power in search and display has allowed it to charge supra-
`competitive prices to advertisers. Although online ad auctions can be designed to drive
`prices to competitive levels, Google’s role in running the auctions on behalf of both
`buyers and sellers (including when Google itself is the seller, as it is for its Google search
`supply and for YouTube and its other properties) gives it the incentive and ability to bias
`auction prices.
`3.
` In the digital advertising market, it is nearly impossible to advertise online
`except through Google’s advertising services. Resulting harms include higher advertising
`prices, higher consumer prices, decreased revenue for online newspapers and other web
`publishers, and overall reduced competition in the buying and selling of digital
`advertising. Consumers, of course, ultimately suffer the consequences of any abuse of
`market power by Google. When Google charges supra-competitive prices to advertisers,
`those excessive payments lead to an increase in the price consumers pay for goods and
`services throughout the economy.
`4.
`Plaintiffs, like other class members placed advertisements online through
`Google as an intermediary. Like other class members, Plaintiffs overpaid and suffered
`
`2
`CLASS ACTION COMPLAINT, CASE NO. 5:20-cv-04130
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`29
`30
`31
`
`
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`Case 5:20-cv-04130 Document 1 Filed 06/22/20 Page 3 of 27
`
`
`
`economic loss resulting from Google’s monopoly in relevant markets, and therefore seek
`damages and injunctive relief.
`
`PARTIES
`5.
`Plaintiff Michael Devaney is a Sarasota, Florida resident who purchased
`digital advertisements from Google during the class period for his supermarket website
`and photography business.
`6.
`Plaintiff Nicholas Arrieta is a Miami, Florida resident who purchased digital
`advertisements from Google during the class period for his online website selling bicycle
`hardware and related retail.
`7.
`Plaintiff Sara Ybarra is a Spokane, Washington resident who purchased
`digital advertisements from Google during the class period for her moving business.
`8.
`Defendant Google LLC is a limited liability company organized under the
`laws of Delaware with its principal place of business in Mountain View, California.
`Google LLC is a technology company that provides internet-related services and
`products, including online advertising technologies and a search engine
`9.
`Defendant Alphabet Inc. is a corporation organized under the laws of
`Delaware with its principal place of business in Mountain View, California. Google LLC
`is a wholly owned subsidiary of Alphabet.
`JURISDICTION AND VENUE
`10. This Court has original jurisdiction over Plaintiffs’ federal antitrust claim
`under Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § 15. The court also has jurisdiction over this action under
`the Class Action Fairness Act (“CAFA”), 28 U.S.C. § 1332(d) because at least one class
`member is of diverse citizenship from Defendants, there are more than 100 class members
`nationally, and the aggregate amount in controversy exceeds $5,000,000.
`11. This Court may exercise jurisdiction over Google because Google’s
`principal place of business is located within this District. Google has established
`sufficient contacts in this District such that personal jurisdiction is appropriate.
`
`3
`CLASS ACTION COMPLAINT, CASE NO. 5:20-cv-04130
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`29
`30
`31
`
`
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`Case 5:20-cv-04130 Document 1 Filed 06/22/20 Page 4 of 27
`
`
`
`12. Venue is proper in this District under 28 U.S.C. § 1391. Google’s principal
`place of business is in this district and it regularly conducts business here. A substantial
`part of the events or omissions giving rise to Plaintiffs’ claims occurred in this District.
`13. Assignment is proper to the San Jose Division of this District under Local
`Rule 3-2(c)-(e), as a substantial part of the events or omissions giving rise to Plaintiffs’
`claims occurred in Santa Clara County.
`FACTUAL ALLEGATIONS
`A. Digital Advertising Background
`14. Advertising campaigns used to be planned and managed by media buyers.
`If that media buyer needed to help a toy manufacturer reach parents of children, she might
`place an ad in Parents Magazine, or in the family section of the local newspaper.
`Advertising used to be something that could be placed, counted, then seen in the front
`cover spread of a magazine.
`15. This is not how digital advertising works today. Digital advertising is
`automated and data-driven, involving data scientists, mathematicians, and computer
`programmers who, behind the scenes, use advanced statistical tools to optimize
`advertising campaigns, by micro-targeting users and constantly tweaking algorithms.
`16.
`In the US, $125 billion was spent on digital advertising in 2019, accounting
`for over half of total ad spending.1
`17. The two big contenders in digital advertising are search and display
`advertising.
`18. Search advertising is a service that businesses pay for to show up in search
`results on search engine result pages, predominately Google Search. Because the
`audience is targeted to those who are actually searching for a product or service, an
`
`
`1See https://www.iab.com/wp-content/uploads/2020/05/FY19-IAB-Internet-Ad-Revenue-
`Report_Final.pdf.
`
`4
`CLASS ACTION COMPLAINT, CASE NO. 5:20-cv-04130
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`29
`30
`31
`
`
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`Case 5:20-cv-04130 Document 1 Filed 06/22/20 Page 5 of 27
`
`
`
`advertiser only pays when the user clicks on the ad. For example, if a user searches for
`sandwich delivery, the search advertising results looks something like this2:
`
`
`
`
`19. Search advertising is designed to reach customers who have already shown
`an interest in purchasing a product or service and may be close to making a purchasing
`decision. Search advertising is attractive to local or small businesses not seeking to reach
`a broad audience. For example, if a citizen finds himself in need of a plumber, and
`searches for plumbers on Google, search advertising will place ads for local plumbers
`above the organic search results.
`20. The downside to search advertising for advertisers themselves is that they
`have to wait for someone to search for their product or service in order to direct
`prospective customers to their business.
`
`
`2See https://www.disruptivestatic.com/wp-content/uploads/2018/02/sandwich-delivery-google-
`search.jpg.
`
`5
`CLASS ACTION COMPLAINT, CASE NO. 5:20-cv-04130
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`29
`30
`31
`
`
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`Case 5:20-cv-04130 Document 1 Filed 06/22/20 Page 6 of 27
`
`
`
`21. Suppliers of display advertising are known as publishers (e.g. online
`newspapers and other content creators). Publishers employ third party tools to find
`advertisers and sell advertising space available on their websites.
`22. Display advertising is the advertising that appears alongside content on
`publishers’ websites. For example, an ad for Dove might appear on a cooking website,
`“myrecipes” as a banner or a side bar3:
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`23.
`In display advertising, an active search for the particular product by the
`internet user is not required; but the key to effective display ads is that they are placed on
`websites likely to be viewed by the advertiser’s target audience and/or those most likely
`to purchase the advertised products or services.
`24.
`$38.1 billion was spent on display advertising in 2019 in the US,
`representing a 13.8% increase from 2018.4 In 2020, spending on display media is
`
`
`3 See https://www.disruptiveadvertising.com/adwords/google-display-network.
`4 See https://www.iab.com/wp-content/uploads/2020/05/FY19-IAB-Internet-Ad-Revenue-
`Report_Final.pdf.
`
`6
`CLASS ACTION COMPLAINT, CASE NO. 5:20-cv-04130
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`29
`30
`31
`
`
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`Case 5:20-cv-04130 Document 1 Filed 06/22/20 Page 7 of 27
`
`
`
`expected to hit $41.9 billion, with a 15.1% year-over-year increase, again outpacing
`search advertising.5
`25. Outside of Google, Facebook, and a few others, the rest of the market, which
`includes thousands and thousands of independent news publishers (that depend on digital
`advertising as their primary source of revenue), will shrink by 11 percent.6
`26. Search advertising and display advertising serve different purposes.
`Advertisers do not regard them as substitutes for each other. The Interactive Advertising
`Bureau separates display and search categorically for annual revenue analysis purposes.
`B. Google Dominates Both Search and Display Online Advertising Services
`27. Alphabet’s total ad revenue in 2019 was $133 billion, making up 82% of
`total revenue.7 Google is estimated to have captured 37.2% of all U.S. digital ad spend in
`2019.8
`28. Google’s revenue from display ads comes from ads placed on Google’s own
`properties (Google Maps, Gmail, etc.) and ads placed with third party publishers (digital
`versions of newspapers, online content creators, etc.). Google sells ad space on third party
`websites to advertisers as an intermediary.
`29. When an ad is viewed through a third-party publisher, for example, The
`Washington Post, Google pays the publisher a portion of the price that the advertiser paid
`to Google for its ad placement services. The portion Google keeps is the “take rate”, or
`difference between what advertiser pays and publisher receives. Google’s take rate is
`estimated to be about 40%.9
`30. Google has an incentive to increase ads placed on its own property sites
`because Google does not have to share the collected price of the ad with a third-party
`publisher.
`
`
`5 See https://www.marketingcharts.com/advertising-trends/spending-and-spenders-111801.
`6 See https://app.hubspot.com/documents/4934439/view/35422028?accessId=bc7916.
`7 See https://abc.xyz/investor/static/pdf/2019Q4_alphabet_earnings_release.pdf.
`8 See https://www.emarketer.com/content/google-maintains-wide-lead-in-net-us-search-ad-revenues.
`9 See https://www.gov.uk/cma-cases/online-platforms-and-digital-advertising-market-study#interim-
`report.
`
`7
`CLASS ACTION COMPLAINT, CASE NO. 5:20-cv-04130
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`29
`30
`31
`
`
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`Case 5:20-cv-04130 Document 1 Filed 06/22/20 Page 8 of 27
`
`
`
`1. Google’s Search Advertising Practices and Market Share
`31. Google by far holds the highest share of search advertising revenue in the
`U.S. In 2019, its share was 73%.10
`32. Google makes space on its search result pages available to advertisers
`through an auction process that occurs each time a user runs a search. Google starts the
`auction by first finding all the ads with keywords matching the search. Google then only
`displays ads with sufficiently high “rank” based on factors like the advertiser’s bid,
`quality of the ad, user location, and type of device user is using. The auction process is
`repeated for every search performed on Google Search, so different searches may lead to
`different auctions, which may lead to different advertisements being displayed.
`33. Although Google claims its prices are set via auction, Google controls and
`frequently raises the price of its search advertising by setting a high reserve price. (An ad
`will not sell if it does not meet the reserve price.) A majority of winning bids are just at
`the reserve price.
`2. Google’s Dominance in the Ad Tech Stack and Display Advertising
`34. Google is a major supplier of display advertising and owns multiple products
`that supply it such as YouTube, Google Maps, and Google Play.
`35. When an internet user visits a website, in the milliseconds that it takes for
`that page to load, there are real-time auctions running in the background that determine
`which ads to display on that particular user’s page. These auctions are run by SSPs and
`DSPs in the ad tech stack as described below.
`36. Suppliers (online publishers) of display advertising employ publisher ad
`servers (PAS) to accept, store, and manage ads, choose where and when ads appear, and
`track the effectiveness of ad campaigns. The placement of ads is determined based on
`bids from advertisers and/or arrangements publishers have with the advertisers.
`
`10 See Id.
`
`
`
`8
`CLASS ACTION COMPLAINT, CASE NO. 5:20-cv-04130
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`29
`30
`31
`
`
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`Case 5:20-cv-04130 Document 1 Filed 06/22/20 Page 9 of 27
`
`
`
`37. Suppliers of ad space/publishers rely on supply side platforms (SSP) to run
`auctions, interface directly with advertisers, and optimize available supply ad-space
`inventory.
`38. The advertisers (or market demand side) rely on advertiser ad servers (AAS)
`to store ads, deliver them to publishers, and records transactions. Advertisers also employ
`demand side platforms (DSP) to purchase digital advertising by bidding in auctions.
`39. Together, the PAS, SSP, AAS, and DSP comprise the ad tech stack. By
`connecting publishers and advertisers, an ad tech provider functions as an intermediary,
`similar to a broker.
`40. Until fairly recently, different firms provided various services in the ad tech
`stack, and intermediaries did not own the publisher or advertise. This is no longer the
`case – After a series of acquisitions, Google now dominates and controls the ad tech
`stack. Since 2007, Google has made at least nine key acquisitions in the interest of
`gaining control of the entire ad tech stack.
`41. Google purchased a publisher ad server in 2007 called DoubleClick, for
`example; the technology from that company served as the basis for Google’s current
`publisher ad server. It acquired AdMob in 2009; AdMob owned technology for serving
`ads on apps. It purchased Invite Media in 2010, which Google developed into its main
`demand side platform. In 2011, it purchased AdMeld, a supply side platform that it
`integrated into AdX, the Google exchange. And in 2014, Google bought Adometry, an
`analytics and attribution provider it then integrated into Google Analytics. Together,
`these acquisitions reveal a sustained effort to occupy the entire ad tech stack as well as
`the related analytics market through mergers.
`42.
`In the supply of advertising space, Google now holds at least 90% of the
`PAS market through multiple products such as Google Ad Manager and Google Double
`Click for Publishers. Google’s AdX product alone holds about 50% of the SSP market.
`
`9
`CLASS ACTION COMPLAINT, CASE NO. 5:20-cv-04130
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`29
`30
`31
`
`
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`Case 5:20-cv-04130 Document 1 Filed 06/22/20 Page 10 of 27
`
`
`
`43. Likewise, on the advertiser-demand side, Google controls a substantial
`majority of the DSP market (reportedly over 62%) and holds a substantial share of AAS
`market.
`44. By consolidating key portions of the ad tech stack for display advertising,
`Google can now readily broker transactions on both sides and steer advertisers to its own
`digital display platforms. Google’s acquisitions and access to every level of display
`advertising service industry have enabled Google to eliminate competition through a
`variety of anticompetitive policies and activities.
`45. Publishers and advertisers have little choice but to go through Google’s
`services.
`46. For example, Nexstar Media Group Inc., the largest local news company in
`the U.S., tested what would happen if it stopped using Google’s technology to place ads
`on its websites. Over several days, the company’s video ad sales plummeted. “That’s a
`huge revenue hit,” said Tony Katsur, senior vice president at Nexstar. After its brief test,
`Nexstar switched back to Google.11
`C. Google Has Used its Dominance as a Search Engine and Other Products to
`Create and Maintain a Monopoly for Display Advertising Services
`1. Google’s Dominance as a Browser and the Significance of User Data
`47. Google has an enormous advantage over advertisers and publishers due to
`sheer volume of information it obtains about consumers. As former CEO Eric Schmidt
`boasted, “We know where you are. We know where you’ve been. We can more or less
`know what you’ve been thinking about.”12
`48. Online advertising is more effective when it is targeted, displaying products
`or services a user is likely to want. Accordingly, user data including gender, age, location,
`and browsing history influences not just the type of ads a user will see, but also price
`advertisers are willing to pay. “The exact same ad, on the same website, at the same time,
`
`11 See https://www.wsj.com/articles/how-google-edged-out-rivals-and-built-the-worlds-dominant-ad-
`machine-a-visual-guide-11573142071.
`12 See https://techcrunch.com/2010/09/07/eric-schmidt-ifa.
`10
`CLASS ACTION COMPLAINT, CASE NO. 5:20-cv-04130
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`29
`30
`31
`
`
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`Case 5:20-cv-04130 Document 1 Filed 06/22/20 Page 11 of 27
`
`
`
`could be worth vastly different amounts to two different buyers depending on how much
`they know about the consumer being targeted,” explains Ari Paparo, now founder and
`CEO of advertising company Beeswax and a former Google executive “User data is
`everything.”
`49. The prices that any company is able to fetch for its ads depend on two crucial
`factors: the ability to identify who is loading the page, and the ability to then connect the
`user’s identity with more information about the user.
`50. The targeting of display ads begins the moment a reader visits any website.
`Typically, the reader’s IP address, location, and the URL of the page the reader visits are
`swiped from the reader’s browser without their explicit knowledge. This information is
`used to run these ad auctions. The goal is to build as specific a portrait about the reader
`as possible—by linking their device with their identity—and cookies are a common tool
`for doing so.
`51. Google has acted to make it harder for its competitors to obtain similar
`information. In early 2020, for instance, Google announced that it would “phase out”
`third-party cookies that helped advertisers target consumers based on demographics, past
`browsing history, and other information. Without third-party cookies, it is much harder
`for advertisers and competitors to efficiently bid on ads. That is not true for Google,
`which continues to have other sources for gleaning robust data on consumers.
`52.
`If a company that sells online ads can know what their readers are reading
`on other sites, then they can target the users based on that information when the user
`returns to their own site. To illustrate the supreme advantage of Google over any other
`publishers, let’s consider two hypothetical online publishers, CNBC and The New York
`Times. For example, say Michael visits CNBC’s website in the mornings and reads about
`the markets, but visits The New York Times in the evenings and only reads the book
`review section. CNBC knows Michael is someone who follows the markets and might
`monetize his view at a $30 CPM (cost per thousand). The Times knows that Michael is
`someone who likes to read books so might only monetize Michael at a $10 CPM. If
`
`11
`CLASS ACTION COMPLAINT, CASE NO. 5:20-cv-04130
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`29
`30
`31
`
`
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`Case 5:20-cv-04130 Document 1 Filed 06/22/20 Page 12 of 27
`
`
`
`the Times can somehow find out that Michael is reading CNBC in the mornings, then
`when Michael visits the Times book section in the evening, the Times can target him as
`someone who follows the markets and monetize him at $30, too.
`53. Would CNBC want to share with the Times what Michael reads on
`cnbc.com? Of course not. The two are competitors on the advertising side of the market.
`If CNBC is selling its audience of financial readers at a cost of $30, and the Times can
`copy CNBC’s readers and their reading patterns, then the Times could theoretically
`undercut CNBC and sell ads targeted to CNBC financial readers for, say, $20 instead of
`$30.
`
`54. But publishers like the Times and CNBC have no choice but to share this
`information with Facebook and Google.
`55. Google, which now tracks users on over 70 percent of the top one million
`sites, also uses its ability to track users across the internet to extract an advantage in
`advertising markets.13 Google tracks users via its analytics and ad-serving products,
`which Google consolidated and rebranded as the Google Marketing Platform.
`56. Google runs auctions through which publishers now sell their own
`advertising. Unlike in finance, there are several auction markets where digital ads trade.
`Anyone can create one. But Google ensures its own advertising inventory (e.g. YouTube)
`can only be bought through their own, proprietary auctions. Google made almost $20
`billion last year from selling other companies’ ads.14 This is why Google today is the
`largest seller of advertising, globally, period.
`2. Google’s Unfair Practices in Search Products
`57. Google operates the default internet search platform in the United States; at
`least 90% of all internet searches are conducted through Google Search. Consequently,
`Google is the dominant source for search advertising. Companies seeking to promote
`their products or services online are de facto required to purchase search advertising space
`
`13https://www.cs.princeton.edu/~arvindn/publications/OpenWPM_1_million_site_tracking_measurem
`ent.pdf.
`14 See https://abc.xyz/investor/static/pdf/20180204_alphabet_10K.pdf?cache=11336e3.
`12
`CLASS ACTION COMPLAINT, CASE NO. 5:20-cv-04130
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`29
`30
`31
`
`
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`Case 5:20-cv-04130 Document 1 Filed 06/22/20 Page 13 of 27
`
`
`
`from Google. Google has taken advantage of this dominance in the search advertising
`market to drive out competition in the separate market for display advertising services.
`58. When a Google Ads account is established for use in placing search
`advertisements, Google Ads is set as the default account for placing both search and
`display advertisements. And to disadvantage rivals, Google restricts access to data
`concerning web searches performed on Google Search.
`59. When consumers run Google searches, Google collects and retains data
`related to the searches. DSPs and advertisers use this information to craft more effective
`advertising campaigns. Google, however, withholds this information from rival DSPs and
`advertisers using rival service providers. The result of this policy is that, in order to gain
`access to the search data over which Google has monopoly control, an advertiser must
`agree to use Google’s products in the separate display advertising services market.
`60. For example, GoogleAds, (a DSP) relies on algorithms that match keywords
`selected by advertisers to user search terms in order to determine which searches would
`be good matches for which search ads.
`61. Google similarly uses its dominance in the video-ad publishing market
`segment to coerce advertisers to use Google’s display advertising services. Google-
`owned YouTube runs up to 50% of all video display ads not appearing on Facebook and
`Amazon. After Google purchased YouTube, it initially made YouTube’s inventory of
`display advertisements available to any advertising service provider. But in 2015, Google
`prevented non-Google advertising service providers from purchasing advertising space
`on YouTube. As a result, if an advertiser wants to purchase any of the valuable
`advertising space on YouTube, it must use Google’s advertising services and cannot use
`any of Google’s rivals’ advertising services.
`62.
`In addition to its ad tech stack services, Google offers Ads Data Hub (ADH)
`which allows advertisers to view data from ad campaigns, which users were reached by
`search ad campaigns, and combine the data with third party data to adjust display ad
`
`13
`CLASS ACTION COMPLAINT, CASE NO. 5:20-cv-04130
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`29
`30
`31
`
`
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`Case 5:20-cv-04130 Document 1 Filed 06/22/20 Page 14 of 27
`
`
`
`strategy. However, ability to use the data has a built-in restriction in that the data can only
`be sent to another Google service and cannot otherwise be exported.
`63. By conditioning advertiser access to Google search data and YouTube’s
`advertising platform on the purchase of Google’s advertising services, Google effectively
`forces advertisers to use Google for all aspects of their campaigns.
`D. Other Forms of Anticompetitive Conduct
`64. Google conceals key information from publishers and advertisers in acting
`as an intermediary. Parties on both sides of the transaction are not aware of the price
`actually paid to Google for an ad placement. Studies have shown that about 15% of
`advertising transaction costs are unaccounted for.15
`65. Google generally maintains a culture of secrecy around its services, an
`indication of market power. Service providers in competitive markets generally must
`provide to their customers detailed accounts of services they provide to justify the prices
`they charge.16
`66.
`In 2016 Google launched AMP for the stated purpose of loading webpages
`faster on mobile devices. AMP pages are listed first in a search, encouraging publishers
`to use them. AMP sends users to content on pages hosted by Google, thereby denying
`content providers as much access to, and data about, their own users as they would
`normally get. This weakens the content providers in the long run, allowing Google’s own
`properties to slowly gain a greater share of consumer attention. Although one might begin
`by characterizing content providers as complements, this creeping strategy by Google to
`
`
`15 PricewatershouseCoopers recently concluded a study in which it attempted to track various
`advertisers’ payments through the ad tech stack. It concluded that a remarkable 15% of ad spend
`simply went missing somewhere between the advertisers and publishers: “15% of advertiser spend –
`an “unknown delta”, representing around one-third of supply chain costs – could not be attributed.”
`See Abi Gibbons, Time for change and transparency in programmatic advertising, ISBA MEMBER
`PORTAL (May 6, 2020), https://www. isba.org.uk/news/time-for-change-and-transparency-in-
`programmatic-advertising/. This study did not focus exclusively on Google’s intermediation services
`but it nonetheless reflects the difficulty advertisers face when trying to understand where their money
`goes, which itself indicates the market is not working efficiently.
`16 https://www.omidyar.com/sites/default/files/Roadmap%20for%20a%20Case%20Against%20Google.pdf.
`14
`CLASS ACTION COMPLAINT, CASE NO. 5:20-cv-04130
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`29
`30
`31
`
`
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`Case 5:20-cv-04130 Document 1 Filed 06/22/20 Page 15 of 27
`
`
`
`host content on its own pages—by a variety of methods—demonstrates that Google views
`content providers as competitors in the long run for the capture of ad dollars. Google
`doesn’t want to develop content so that it wins more Pulitzer Prizes than the New York
`Times or the Washington Post; that is an expensive undertaking. Rather, Google wants
`to host that attractive content so it can capture the ad dollars that otherwise would go to
`those publishers. That is the reason it steers consumers to Google properties and away
`from content providers. That conduct constitutes foreclosure of horizontal competitors.
`E. Government Investigations into Google’s Monopolistic Conduct
`67.
`In July 2019, the U.S. Department of Justice announced that it had opened
`an investigation into whether Google is committing illegal monopolistic acts. The DOJ
`stated that its probe would focus on whether and how Google and other leading online
`platforms “have achieved market power and are engaging in practices that have reduced
`competition, stifled innovation, or otherwise harmed consumers.”
`68.
`In September 2019, 48 state attorneys general, led by Texas Attorney
`General Ken Paxton, disclosed their own probe into whether Google is violating the
`antitrust laws. In announcing the investigation, Paxton referred to “evidence that
`Google’s business practices may have undermined consumer choice, stifled innovation,
`violated users’ privacy, and put Google in control of the flow and dissemination of online
`information.”
`69. On May 15, 2020, the Wall Street Journal reported—based on information
`from “people familiar with the matter”—that both the DOJ and the state attorneys general
`likely will file antitrust lawsuits against Google as soon as the summer and are well into
`planning for such litigation. The Journal reported that “all signs point toward [the DOJ]
`bringing a case” and that “[m]uch of the states’ investigation has focused on Google’s
`online advertising business. The company owns the dominant tool at every link in the
`complex chain between online publishers and advertisers.”17
`
`
`17 See https://www.wsj.com/articles/justice-department-state-attorneys-general-likely-to-bring-
`antitrust-lawsuits-against-google-11589573622?mod=searchresults&page=1&pos=17.
`15
`CLASS ACTION COMPLAINT, CASE NO. 5:20-cv-04130
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`29
`30
`31
`
`
`
`

`

`
`
`
`
`Case 5:20-cv-04130 Document 1 Filed 06/22/20 Page 16 of 27
`
`
`
`70. Google has also faced regulatory action in Europe. The European
`Commission fined Google $2.7 billion in 2017 for rigging search results to favor its own
`online shopping portal and $1.7 billion in 2019 for dictating to other websites how they
`can display search results from Google’s competitors.
`71. The U.K. is also considering limiting Google’s ability to set self-serving
`defaults and enforcing data sharing and/or feature interoperability to help rivals compete
`in re

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket