throbber
No. 15-777
`
`
`
`IN THE
`Supreme Court of the United States
`__________
`
`SAMSUNG ELECTRONICS CO., LTD., SAMSUNG
`ELECTRONICS AMERICA, INC., SAMSUNG
`TELECOMMUNICATIONS AMERICA, LLC,
`Petitioners,
`
`Respondent.
`
`v.
`
`APPLE INC.,
`__________
`
`On Writ of Certiorari
`to the United States Court of Appeals
`for the Federal Circuit
`__________
`
`BRIEF OF TIFFANY AND COMPANY, ADIDAS
`AG, AND JENNY YOO COLLECTION, INC., AS
`AMICI CURIAE IN SUPPORT OF RESPONDENT
`__________
`
`MICHAEL J. GOTTLIEB
` Counsel of Record
`JESSICA E. PHILLIPS
`CAIN M. NORRIS
`BOIES, SCHILLER & FLEXNER LLP
`5301 Wisconsin Ave., N.W.
`Washington, D.C. 20015
`(202) 237-2727
`MGottlieb@bsfllp.com
`
`Counsel for Amici Curiae
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`

`
`
`
`i
`
`TABLE OF CONTENTS
`
`Page
`TABLE OF AUTHORITIES .................................... iii 
`INTEREST OF AMICI CURIAE ............................. 1 
`SUMMARY OF ARGUMENT .................................. 1 
`ARGUMENT ............................................................. 3 
`PATENTS
`PROVIDE
`IMPORTANT
`I.  DESIGN
`INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY PROTECTION
`FOR
`ESTABLISHED AND EMERGING DESIGNERS IN THE
`FASHION INDUSTRY .............................................. 3 
`A.  The Fashion Industry is an Important Driver
`of U.S. Economic Growth ............................... 3 
`B.  Innovative Design is Critical to the Fashion
`Industry .......................................................... 5 
`C.  Design Pirates Cause Substantial Economic
`and Creative Harm to both Established and
`Emerging Fashion Designers ........................ 7 
`D.  Design Patents are an Important Tool for
`Designers to Protect Their Designs ............ 11 
`II.  FURTHER LIMITING THE TOTAL PROFITS DAMAGES
`REMEDY WOULD HARM THE FASHION INDUSTRY
`AND THE U.S. ECONOMY ..................................... 14 
`A.  The Total Profits Remedy Effectively
`Dissuades Design Pirates ............................ 15 
`B.  Without a Meaningful Remedy, Design
`Patents Cannot Create
`the
`Incentives
`Necessary to “Promote the Progress of …
`Useful Arts” .................................................. 17 
`
`
`
`

`
`ii
`
`
`C.  This Court Should Not Ignore the Plain
`Language of § 289 and Congress’s Plain
`Intent in Passing It Based on Hypothetical
`Policy Concerns ............................................ 20 
`CONCLUSION ....................................................... 21 
`
`
`
`

`
`
`
`iii
`
`TABLE OF AUTHORITIES
`
`Cases 
`Birdsall v. Coolidge,
`93 U.S. 64 (1876) ............................................... 17
`
`Fashion Originators Guild of Am., Inc., v. Fed.
`Trade Comm’n,
`114 F.2d 80 (2d Cir. 1940) ................................ 12
`Fruit of the Loom, Inc. v. Girouard,
`994 F.2d 1359 (9th Cir. 1993) ............................. 6
`
`Fun-Damental Too, Ltd. v. Gemmy Indus.
`Corp.,
`111 F.3d 993 (2d Cir. 1997)............................... 13
`Jay Franco & Sons, Inc. v. Franek,
`615 F.3d 855 (7th Cir. 2010) ............................. 14
`
`Octane Fitness, LLC v. Icon Health & Fitness,
`Inc.,
`572 U.S. __ (2014) ............................................. 18
`
`Soptra Fabrics Corp. v. Stafford Knitting
`Mills, Inc.,
`490 F.2d 1092 (2d Cir. 1974) ............................. 13
`Wal-Mart Stores Inc. v. Samara Brothers, Inc.,
`529 U.S. 205 (2000) ..................................... 14, 16
`Constitutional Provisions 
`U.S. CONST. art. I, § 8, cl. 8 .................................... 19
`Statutes 
`15 U.S.C. § 1127 ..................................................... 13
`
`
`
`

`
`iv
`
`
`17 U.S.C. § 1302 ..................................................... 12
`35 U.S.C § 171 ........................................................ 11
`35 U.S.C. § 173 ....................................................... 11
`35 U.S.C. § 283 ................................................. 15, 16
`35 U.S.C. § 284 ........................................... 15, 16, 17
`35 U.S.C. § 285 ....................................................... 18
`35 U.S.C. § 289 ............................................... passim
`Regulations 
`80 Fed. Reg. 17,918 (Apr. 2, 2015) ......................... 11
`Other Authorities 
`Biana Borukhovich, Fashion Design: The Work
`Of Art That Is Still Unrecognized In The
`United States, 9 WAKE FOREST INTELL.
`PROP. L.J. 155 (2009) ................................... 7, 8, 9
`Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Dep’t Of
`Labor, Occupational Outlook Handbook:
`Fashion Designers (2014-2015 ed.) ..................... 6
`Council of Fashion Designers of Am., CFDA
`Applauds Design Prohibition Act (Dec. 31,
`2009) .................................................................... 7
`Diane von Furstenberg, Fashion Deserves
`Copyright Protection, L.A. Times, Aug. 24,
`2007 ................................................................... 10
`
`
`
`

`
`v
`
`
`Econ. Info. & Research Dep’t of L.A. Cty. Econ.
`Dev. Corp., Los Angeles Area Fashion
`Industry Profile (2004) ........................................ 4
`Elizabeth Ferrill & Tina Tanhehco, Protecting
`the Material World, 12 N.C. J. L. & TECH.
`251 (2011) ........................................................ 7, 8
`H.R. Rep. No. 49-1966 (1886) ....................... 5, 17, 20
`Joint Econ. Comm., U.S. Cong., The Economic
`Impact of the Fashion Industry
`(Sept. 2015) ...................................................... 4, 5
`Karl T. Ulrich & Steven D. Eppinger, Product
`Design and Development (5th ed. 2012) ............. 5
`Laura C. Marshall, Catwalk Copycats: Why
`Congress Should Adopt a Modified Version
`of the Design Piracy Prohibition Act, 14 J.
`INTELL. PROP. L. 305 (2007) ................................ 6
`N.Y.C. Econ. Dev. Corp., Fashion.NYC.2020
`(2012) ................................................................... 4
`OECD & EUIPO, Trade in Counterfeit and
`Pirated Goods: Mapping the Economic
`Impact (2016) ....................................................... 9
`S. Rep. No. 49-206 (1886) ................................. 17, 19
`Susan Scafidi, Intellectual Property and
`Fashion Design, in 1 Intellectual Property
`and Information Wealth 115 (Peter K. Yu
`ed., 2006) ........................................................... 12
`
`
`
`

`
`vi
`
`
`Susan Scafidi, Written Statement on H.R.
`5055, The Design Piracy Prohibition Act 2
`(July 27, 2006) ..................................................... 6
`U.S. Patent & Trademark Office, Design
`Patents, January 1, 1991—December 31,
`2015 (Mar. 2016) ............................................... 12
`U.S. Patent & Trademark Office, Manual of
`Patent Examining Procedure (2015) ................ 11
`
`
`
`

`
`1
`
`
`
`INTEREST OF AMICI CURIAE1
`Amici curiae are members of the fashion
`industry who have secured design patents to help
`protect their innovative designs.
`For almost 180 years, amicus Tiffany & Co. has
`been one of the most iconic luxury brands in
`American fashion. Amicus Adidas AG is one of the
`largest sportswear manufacturers in the world.
`Amicus Jenny Yoo Collection, Inc., is an American
`innovator in bridal fashion. Amici make substantial
`investments in developing novel designs, and have
`been securing design patents since the nineteenth,
`twentieth, and twenty-first centuries respectively to
`protect their innovations from design pirates.
`Amici have an interest in highlighting the
`unique function of design patents in the fashion
`industry, which differs in various ways from the
`technology industry highlighted in the parties’
`briefs. Moreover, the Court’s decision in this case
`will directly affect the value of amici’s design
`patents and by extension the distinctive designs
`that those patents protect.
`SUMMARY OF ARGUMENT
`fashion
`industry
`is of critical social,
`The
`cultural, and economic significance. It is a $1.2
`trillion global industry based on the constant
`creation of fresh and groundbreaking designs.
`
`
`1 Pursuant to Supreme Court Rule 37.3(a), all parties have
`consented to the filing of this brief. Pursuant to Rule 37.6,
`amici certify that no counsel for a party authored this brief in
`whole or in part, and no persons other than amici curiae or
`their counsel made a monetary contribution to its preparation
`or submission.
`
`
`
`

`
`2
`
`
`Fashion designers invest enormous amounts of
`capital, time, and sweat equity
`in creating
`innovative designs
`that
`capture
`consumers’
`attention and drive consumption. Design pirates
`capitalize on the huge investments made by fashion
`designers by copying only popular and successful
`designs. They operate swiftly and anonymously
`from off-shore havens, producing low-cost, high-
`volume knockoff goods that saturate the market
`and prevent legitimate designers from reaping the
`rewards of their investments. In doing so, design
`pirates create a disincentive to invest in future
`designs and inhibit creativity.
`Enforcing intellectual property rights against
`design pirates is notoriously difficult. Although
`trademark
`law and
`copyright
`law provide
`protection for some design elements—trademark
`protects a recognizable logo, name, or mark while
`copyrights protect specific aspects of a garment
`such as the fabric design or individual pattern—
`they do not protect the overall appearance of most
`fashion designs. Design patents do provide
`protection to fashion designers for new, original,
`and ornamental designs for articles of manufacture
`but it is still extremely difficult to enforce design
`patent rights against design pirates, who often are
`anonymous, fly-by-night, off-shore entities. Because
`the
`inherent
`limitations of these
`intellectual
`property regimes leave fashion designers open to
`encroachment of design pirates, the total profits
`regime enshrined in § 289 of the Patent Act (35
`U.S.C. § 289) is critical to address the harm caused
`by design piracy. The total profits rule helps to
`ensure
`that designers have
`the appropriate
`incentives and rewards to make investments in
`
`
`
`

`
`3
`
`
`innovative designs. By ensuring that a design
`pirate
`cannot
`profit
`from
`design
`patent
`infringement, § 289 discourages many would-be
`design pirates and, consequently, encourages
`investment in creative designs.
`Rewriting § 289 to limit a design patentee’s
`remedy to the portion of the infringer’s profits that
`the patentee can prove is due to the patented
`design elements, rather than the infringer’s total
`profits on the article of manufacture, would
`significantly reduce the protection provided by
`design patents. Other measures of damages cannot
`provide
`the same
`level of deterrence. And
`engrafting an apportionment damages scheme onto
`design patents would increase the costs of enforcing
`design patents while decreasing the efficiency of
`litigation and
`the
`likelihood of settlement.
`Moreover, the Court should not ignore the original
`intent of § 289, which applies to any article of
`manufacture to which a patented design is applied,
`by prioritizing hypothetical and
`speculative
`concerns over the very real concerns of the fashion
`industry.
`
`ARGUMENT
`I. DESIGN PATENTS PROVIDE
`IMPORTANT
`INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY PROTECTION FOR
`ESTABLISHED AND EMERGING DESIGNERS IN
`THE FASHION INDUSTRY
`A. The Fashion Industry is an Important
`Driver of U.S. Economic Growth
`The fashion industry represents one of the
`largest drivers of economic growth in the United
`States, with nearly $370 billion spent annually on
`
`
`
`

`
`4
`
`
`apparel and footwear in America. Joint Econ.
`Comm., U.S. Cong., The Economic Impact of the
`Fashion Industry at 1 (Sept. 2015), available at
`http://www.jec.senate.gov/public/_cache/files/2523ae
`10-9f05-4b8a-8954-631192dcd77f/jec-fashion-
`industry-report----sept-2015-update.pdf. New York,
`which is the largest retail market in the country
`and the fashion capitol of the United States,
`generates more than $18 billion in annual retail
`sales. Id. at 3. New York Fashion Week’s yearly
`economic
`impact
`includes approximately $532
`million in direct visitor spending and $865 million
`in total economic impact each year. N.Y.C. Econ.
`Dev. Corp., Fashion.NYC.2020 10 (2012), available
`at http://www.nycedc.com/resource/fashionnyc2020.
`The fashion industry employs more than 1.8
`million workers across the country in a wide range
`of occupations, including computer programmers,
`lawyers, accountants, copywriters, social media
`directors, project managers, sewing machine
`operators,
`tailors,
`fabric
`and
`apparel
`patternmakers, and, of course, fashion designers.
`Joint Econ. Comm., supra, at 1-2. There are
`roughly 18,000 fashion designers working in the
`United States—a figure that has grown by over 50
`percent in the past ten years. Id. at 2.
`The
`fashion
`industry
`is structurally and
`organizationally diverse. See Econ.
`Info. &
`Research Dep’t, L.A. Cty. Econ. Dev. Corp., Los
`Angeles Area Fashion Industry Profile (2003),
`available at http://www.laedc.org/reports/fashion-
`2003.pdf
`(noting
`that
`fashion
`“is a highly
`sophisticated industry involving fashion & market
`research, brand
`licensing/intellectual property
`rights, design, materials engineering …, product
`
`
`
`

`
`and
`
`finally
`
`5
`
`marketing,
`
`
`manufacturing,
`distribution”).
`It includes large design houses, independent
`one-person design shops, wholesalers, and major
`international retailers. Although
`the
`fashion
`industry in the United States is concentrated in
`New York and California, “fashion is now having a
`big economic impact not only in fashion centers on
`the coasts, but also in smaller cities around the
`country.” Joint Econ. Comm., supra, at 1. Dallas,
`Kansas City, Columbus, and Nashville are
`emerging as fashion centers and are producing
`designers that are impacting trends in the industry.
`Id. at 4.
`B. Innovative Design is Critical to the
`Fashion Industry
`Fashion designers are “the profession at the
`heart of the industry’s creative process.” Id. at 2. It
`is a designer’s inventive and fresh designs that
`inspire consumers, capture the attention of the
`fashion media, and allow fashion designers to
`compete with one another for sales. As Congress
`recognized more than a century ago, “it is the
`design that sells the article.” H.R. Rep. No. 49-
`1966, at 3 (1886).
`Fashion designs serve as a form of self-
`expression for consumers who purchase clothing,
`shoes, or accessories from their preferred designers.
`“An attractive product may be associated with high
`fashion and image and will likely create a strong
`sense of pride among its owners.” Karl T. Ulrich &
`Steven D. Eppinger, Product Design and
`Development 213 (5th ed. 2012). Indeed, consumers
`purchase fashion not only for utilitarian reasons
`
`
`
`

`
`6
`
`
`but also to make a fashion statement. Fruit of the
`Loom, Inc. v. Girouard, 994 F.2d 1359, 1361 (9th
`Cir. 1993)
`(noting
`that allegedly
`infringing
`underwear was purchased “for a fashion statement”
`and not for “utilitarian purposes” and that they
`were “chosen with care”); see also Susan Scafidi,
`Written Statement on H.R. 5055, The Design Piracy
`Prohibition Act 2
`(July 27, 2006)
`(“Fashion,
`however, is not just about covering the body—it is
`about creative expression.”). Participating in trends
`and being “in-fashion”
`is one way
`in which
`individuals engage
`in social
`life. Promoting
`innovation in fashion by protecting fashion designs
`therefore has an inherent social and cultural
`benefit.
`Because innovative design is so important in the
`fashion industry, designers invest substantial time,
`effort, and resources in designs that are original,
`groundbreaking, and that have consumer appeal. A
`designer typically spends eighteen to twenty-four
`months from the time the design is first sketched to
`the manufacture of the final product. Laura C.
`Marshall, Catwalk Copycats: Why Congress Should
`Adopt a Modified Version of the Design Piracy
`Prohibition Act, 14 J. INTELL. PROP. L. 305, 311
`(2007); see also Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S.
`Dep’t Of Labor, Occupational Outlook Handbook:
`Fashion Designers (2014-2015 ed.), available at
`http://www.bls.gov/ooh/arts-and-design/fashion-
`designers.htm#tab-3 (2007) (noting that “fashion
`designers work many hours to meet production
`deadlines or prepare for fashion shows”). After a
`design debuts on the runway, it may still take
`another four months for the product to reach a
`retail store. Elizabeth Ferrill & Tina Tanhehco,
`
`
`
`

`
`7
`
`
`Protecting the Material World, 12 N.C. J. L. & TECH.
`251, 264 (2011). Just one season for a fashion
`design can cost millions of dollars. Id.
`Given the substantial economic stakes, ensuring
`effective and thorough protection of original designs
`from knockoff artists is a high priority for fashion
`designers. A total profits damages regime helps to
`ensure that investments in innovative designs are
`properly incentivized and rewarded.
`C. Design Pirates Cause Substantial
`Economic and Creative Harm to both
`Established and Emerging Fashion
`Designers
`Fashion designers and the fashion industry are
`under siege from legions of design pirates and
`knockoff artists. Often these design pirates are
`anonymous, off-shore entities that strategically
`produce low-cost, high volume copies of popular and
`successful designs, thereby capitalizing on the
`investments made by fashion designers at great
`economic and creative harm to those designers and
`the industry as a whole.
`increasingly
`the
`Design piracy
`“describes
`prevalent practice of enterprises that seek to profit
`from the invention of others by producing copies of
`original designs under a different label.” Council of
`Fashion Designers of Am., CFDA Applauds Design
`Prohibition Act (Dec. 31, 2009), http://cfda.com/the-
`latest/cfda-applauds-design-prohibition-act. Design
`piracy is distinct from counterfeiting, which is “the
`practice of imitating fashion designs with the intent
`to deceive buyers of the apparel’s true content or
`origin by mimicking the details of the design and
`the name brand logo.” Biana Borukhovich, Fashion
`
`
`
`

`
`8
`
`
`Design: The Work Of Art That Is Still Unrecognized
`In The United States, 9 WAKE FOREST INTELL. PROP.
`L.J. 155, 156 (2009). Counterfeiting is a type of
`design piracy because “[o]ne has to copy the design
`first before attaching the counterfeit label. Design
`piracy is counterfeiting without the label.” Id.
`(citing
`Laura Goldman,
`Fashion
`Piracy,
`BPCOUNCIL (2007)).
`Although design piracy is not new, it has been
`exacerbated
`by
`technology
`and
`increased
`information dissemination, the sum of which allows
`copying to occur faster, on a larger scale, and at a
`lower cost than ever before. When design piracy
`thrives, the investment of capital, time, and effort
`designers make to produce their original designs is
`eviscerated. In contrast to the two-year time-frame
`high-end designers invest in their designs, design
`pirates take as few as four to six weeks to get their
`products to the market. Ferrill & Tanhehco, supra,
`at 264. High-end designs are available on the
`internet within hours of debuting on the runway or
`the red carpet. Id. at 266. Fashion websites and
`celebrity blogs display photographs of the designs
`from every angle, and often include close up images
`of design details with accompanying editorial
`descriptions of the designs. Id. Technology thus
`ensures that design pirates not only do not need to
`wait for the originals to hit the showroom floors,
`but they need not incur the expense of traveling to
`the runway shows or the red carpet events to copy
`designs for mass production. Id. Indeed, a pattern
`based on a website photograph or Internet
`broadcast of a runway show can be transmitted
`electronically to a low-cost contract manufacturer
`who can produce products in high volumes. And
`
`
`
`

`
`9
`
`
`electronic communications and express shipping
`ensure that finished products are brought to
`market on an express timeframe.
`Design piracy causes substantial economic
`harms. Earlier this year, the European Union (EU)
`and the Organisation for Economic Co-operation
`and Development (OECD) issued a report that
`found that the value of imported fake goods
`worldwide was $461 billion in 2013.2 See OECD &
`EUIPO, Trade in Counterfeit and Pirated Goods:
`Mapping the Economic Impact 11 (2016), available
`at www.oecd.org/governance/trade-in-counterfeit-
`and-pirated-goods-9789264252653-en.htm.
`The
`report noted that U.S., Italian, and French brands
`were the hardest hit. Id. at 50. The report also
`found that the United States was “[t]he top
`countr[y] whose companies had their intellectual
`property
`rights
`infringed” and
`that
`those
`companies’ “brands or patents were affected by 20%
`of the knock-offs….” Id. A similar report from 2008
`found that counterfeiting and design piracy cost the
`U.S. economy between $200-$250 billion per year,
`and that knockoff merchandise was responsible for
`the loss of 750,000 American jobs. Borukhovich,
`supra, at 157 (citing Int’l Anticounterfeiting Coal.,
`GET REAL – The Truth About Counterfeiting
`(2008)).
`
`
`2 The report includes figures on counterfeit and knockoff
`goods. Because design piracy is not a criminal offense in the
`United States, it is difficult to find figures for knockoffs apart
`from counterfeits. However, because counterfeiting is a type of
`design piracy (see supra at 8), these figures serve as a
`meaningful proxy for the economic consequences caused by
`knockoffs.
`
`
`
`

`
`10
`
`
`Knockoffs affect established designers through
`the loss of substantial revenue and exclusive
`control over the use of original designs, but fashion
`piracy has an especially devastating impact on
`emerging designers. While established fashion
`designers and couture houses have the resources to
`survive copycat designs, knockoffs can and have
`stalled the rise of emerging designers, who “remain
`vulnerable to knockoff artists” who “can effectively
`put young designers out of business before they
`even have a chance.” Diane von Furstenberg,
`Fashion Deserves Copyright Protection, L.A. Times,
`Aug. 24, 2007, http://www.latimes.com/opinion/la-
`oew-furstenberg24aug24-story.html. Design piracy
`devalues the designer’s creation before he or she
`can reap any return on the investment.
`Knockoffs
`further harm
`established and
`emerging designers alike by disincentivizing
`creative design efforts. Developing fashion designs
`is neither easy nor inexpensive. As described above,
`it is a time-intensive, iterative process that may or
`may not result in a commercial success. It is not
`easy for fashion designers to predict what will
`resonate with the consuming public given how
`swiftly the fashion winds shift. And many fashion
`designs never make it to the runway or the
`showroom. Design pirates avoid
`the
`costs
`associated with creating original designs through
`that trial and error process and capitalize on the
`investments made by the fashion designers at a
`fraction of the cost by only copying popular and
`successful designs. If efforts by knockoff artists are
`not dissuaded by the threat of an intellectual
`property regime with appropriate remedies, there is
`far less of an incentive for fashion designers to
`
`
`
`

`
`11
`
`
`continue to invest the time, effort, and funds to
`produce goods that will resonate with consumers.
`D. Design Patents are an Important Tool
`for Designers to Protect Their Designs
`Design patents are an important tool for fashion
`designers because they offer protection for original
`designs where other intellectual property regimes
`fall short.
`Design patents provide patent protection to
`inventors of “new, original, and ornamental design
`for an article of manufacture.” 35 U.S.C § 171.
`These patents protect the way something looks, as
`opposed to more commonly known utility patents,
`which protect the way something is used and
`works. U.S. Patent & Trademark Office, Manual of
`Patent Examining Procedure §1502.01
`(2015),
`available at https://mpep.uspto.gov/RDMS/MPEP/
`current#/current/d0e150114.html (noting as a point
`of contrast that “a utility patent protects the way
`an article is used and works, while a design patent
`protects the way an article looks”). The design for
`an article consists of the visual characteristics
`embodied in or applied to an article. Id. at § 1502.
`The subject matter of a design patent application
`may relate to the configuration or shape of an
`article, to the surface ornamentation applied to an
`article, or to the combination of configuration and
`surface ornamentation. Id. Design patents grant
`the patent owner a statutory limited monopoly for
`15 years from the date of grant (or 14 years for
`applications filed before May 13, 2015), and are not
`renewable. 35 U.S.C. § 173; 80 Fed. Reg. 17,918,
`17,918 (Apr. 2, 2015).
`
`
`
`

`
`12
`
`
`Fashion designers have increasingly turned to
`design patents to protect their original creations.3
`In part, this is because fashion design lacks
`protection against copying under other intellectual
`property regimes in the United States. While
`certain design elements may be protected through
`the application of copyright, trademark, or trade
`dress law, the overall appearance of most fashion
`designs is still vulnerable to the encroachment of
`design pirates. See Susan Scafidi, Intellectual
`Property and Fashion Design, in 1 Intellectual
`Property and Information Wealth 115, 121 (Peter
`K. Yu ed., 2006).
`For example, copyright laws provide minimal
`protection for fashion designs. A fashion design
`does not receive copyright protection if it is
`“embodied in a useful article that was made public
`by the designer or owner in the United States or a
`foreign country more than 2 years before the date of
`the application
`for
`registration” under
`the
`Copyright Act. 17 U.S.C. § 1302. Courts have held
`that articles of clothing are “useful articles” not
`generally granted copyright protection. See, e.g.,
`Fashion Originators Guild of Am., Inc., v. Fed.
`Trade Comm’n, 114 F.2d 80, 84 (2d Cir. 1940)
`(stating that dress designs are not copyrightable
`and “fall into the public demesne without reserve”),
`aff’d 312 U.S. 457 (1941). Copyrights are thus only
`available to protect specific parts of a garment or
`accessory such as the fabric design or individual
`
`3 Although statistics are not available for all fashion-related
`design patents specifically, design patent applications have
`increased overall each year since 2009. See generally U.S.
`Patent & Trademark Office, Design Patents, January 1,
`1991‒December 31, 2015 (Mar. 2016).
`
`
`
`

`
`13
`
`
`patterns for each garment, but not the entire design
`of the item. See, e.g., Soptra Fabrics Corp. v.
`Stafford Knitting Mills, Inc., 490 F.2d 1092, 1094
`(2d Cir. 1974).
`Trademark law is limited in its protection of
`fashion designs because
`it protects only a
`recognizable logo, name, or mark. To achieve
`trademark protection under the Lanham Act, the
`name or logo must distinguish it from other goods
`in commerce. 15 U.S.C. § 1127. Thus, if a designer
`as a matter of taste or marketing chooses not to
`have a visible logo on a design, then trademark
`laws will not provide any protection for that design.
`In addition, established and prominent fashion
`houses are more
`likely to be protected by
`trademark law because their famous brands have
`acquired distinctiveness. Emerging designs, by
`contrast, do not yet have the benefit of name
`recognition.
`Trade-dress law is a subset of trademark law,
`and it also provides only limited protection for
`fashion designs. Trade dress is the totality of
`elements in which a product or service is packaged
`or presented. The elements combined create a
`whole visual image for a consumer and may be
`protected if it becomes a type of identifier or symbol
`of the source of origin. See Fun-Damental Too, Ltd.
`v. Gemmy Indus. Corp., 111 F.3d 993, 999 (2d Cir.
`1997) (holding that trade dress “encompasses the
`design and appearance of the product together with
`all the elements making up the overall image that
`serves to identify the product presented to the
`consumer”). This Court has held that product
`designs
`like garments are never “inherently
`distinctive” or
`intrinsically capable of source
`
`
`
`

`
`14
`
`
`identification. Wal-Mart Stores Inc. v. Samara
`Brothers, Inc., 529 U.S. 205, 209-215 (2000).
`Because U.S. copyright, trademark, and trade-
`dress laws offer incomplete protection for fashion
`designs, designers need the protection afforded by
`patent designs—and
`its total profits remedy
`provision—to protect clothing and accessories from
`design pirates and knockoff artists.
`II. FURTHER LIMITING THE TOTAL PROFITS
`DAMAGES REMEDY WOULD HARM THE FASHION
`INDUSTRY AND THE U.S. ECONOMY
`The efficacy of design patents will be
`significantly reduced if this Court rewrites § 289 to
`limit a design patentee’s remedy to the portion of
`the infringer’s profits that the patentee can prove is
`attributable to the patented design elements,
`rather than the infringer’s total profits on the
`article of manufacture. As discussed, the remedy for
`design patent infringement is generally the only
`remedy available to fashion designers for piracy of
`their creative works. Jay Franco & Sons, Inc. v.
`Franek, 615 F.3d 855, 860
`(7th Cir. 2010).
`Weakening that remedy therefore weakens fashion
`designers’ right to their designs and by extension
`weakens the incentive for designers to innovate—
`both by reducing the likely gains from innovation
`and by increasing the likely gains from design
`piracy. With less protection from knockoffs and
`copycats,
`fashion designers, as well as
`the
`American fashion industry and the U.S. economy as
`a whole, will suffer.
`
`
`
`

`
`15
`
`
`A. The Total Profits Remedy Effectively
`Dissuades Design Pirates
`Section 289 ensures that a design pirate cannot
`profit from design patent infringement and thus
`discourages most would-be infringers—particularly
`large, high-volume infringers who have little hope
`of avoiding detection. Importantly, § 289 is in many
`cases the only effective deterrent available to
`fashion designers.
`total profits remedy, design
`Without
`the
`innovators would be forced to rely on the general
`measure of patent damages found in § 284. Under
`that provision, design infringers could expect that
`even
`if their
`infringement was detected and
`litigated, they would pay only a “reasonable
`royalty” for the
`infringing design. Given the
`investments required to bring fashion products to
`market, such a royalty award might well leave the
`infringer better off for having infringed the design
`patent. Consequently, the threat of such an award
`will have little to no deterrent effect. Likewise, the
`other measure of damages in § 284, damages
`sufficient to compensate the patentee for their
`losses, is unlikely to deter design pirates. Design
`patentees face intense challenges proving causation
`and damages from infringement, especially where,
`as in the fashion industry, the patentee primarily
`sells its original designs into a different market
`segment than the ones in which infringers sell their
`knockoffs.
`Other remedies, such as injunctions from the
`International Trade Commission or the courts
`under § 283 are also unlikely to deter infringement
`in fast-moving industries like fashion. It takes time
`
`
`
`

`
`16
`
`
`for design patentees to detect infringement, identify
`the infringing entity, send cease-and-desist letters,
`and eventually institute litigation (assuming the
`infringing party can be identified and located); it
`takes longer still to secure an injunction. Obtaining
`an exclusion order to enable Customs enforcement
`of a design patent is no faster. Given the speed of
`the fashion trend cycle, and the fly-by-night
`character of many overseas infringers, design
`pirates would likely conclude in many cases that
`infringement would likely be profitable despite the
`risk of an injunction—an assessment they are less
`likely to make when the design patent owner is
`backed by a plausible threat of disgorging the
`infringer’s total profits. Cf. Wal-Mart Stores, 529
`U.S. at 214 (noting the deterrence effect from “the
`plausible threat of successful suit”). The time,
`expense, and difficulty of even identifying and
`locating design pirates, along with the time and
`expense of litigation, already make effective design
`patent enforcement unusually difficult. A new
`interpretation of § 289, significantly reducing a
`design pirate’s expected losses in litigation, would
`make it harder still, rendering the patent right
`functionally worthless in many cases.
`Given the inability of §§ 283 & 28

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket