throbber
Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 1 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`No. 21-2603
`
`IN THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
`FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT
`
`FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION,
`
`Plaintiff-Appellee
`
`V.
`
`HACKENSACK MERIDIAN HEALTH, INC. AND
`ENGLEWOOD HEALTHCARE FOUNDATION,
`
`Defendants-Appellants
`
`On Appeal from the United States District Court for the
`District of New Jersey, Case No. 2:20-cv-18140
`The Honorable John Michael Vazquez
`
`BRIEF OF THE STATES OF PENNSYLVANIA, CALIFORNIA,
`COLORADO, CONNECTICUT, DELAWARE, IDAHO, ILLINOIS,
`INDIANA, MARYLAND, MASSACHUSETTS, MICHIGAN,
`MINNESOTA, NEBRASKA, NEVADA, NEW HAMPSHIRE, NEW
`MEXICO, NEW YORK, NORTH CAROLINA, NORTH DAKOTA,
`OREGON, RHODE ISLAND, VIRGINIA, WASHINGTON,
`WISCONSIN, THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA, AND THE
`TERRITORY OF GUAM AS AMICUS CURIAE IN SUPPORT OF
`THE APPELLEE
`_______________
`
`
`JOSH SHAPIRO
`Attorney General of Pennsylvania
`James A. Donahue, III
`Executive Deputy Attorney General
`
`ROB BONTA
`Attorney General of California
`Renuka George
`Senior Assistant Attorney General
`
`

`

`Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 2 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`Emilio Varanini
`Supervising Deputy Attorney General
`455 Golden Gate Avenue, 11th Floor
` San Francisco, CA 94102
` Tel: (415) 510-3541
` Email: Emilio.Varanini@doj.ca.gov
`
`*Tracy W. Wertz
`Chief Deputy Attorney General
`Jennifer A. Thomson
`Senior Deputy Attorney General
`Abigail U. Wood
`Deputy Attorney General
`14th Floor Strawberry Square,
`Harrisburg, PA 17120
`Tel: (717) 787-4530
`Email: twertz@attorneygeneral.gov
`*Counsel of Record for Amici Curiae
`
`[Additional Counsel Listed on Next Page ]
`
`

`

`Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 3 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`PHILIP J. WEISER
`Attorney General
`State of Colorado
`1300 Broadway, 10th Floor
`Denver, Colorado 80203
`Tel: 720-508-6000
`
`WILLIAM TONG
`Attorney General of Connecticut
`165 Capitol Avenue
`Hartford, Connecticut 06106
`Tel: (860) 571-1258
`
`KATHLEEN JENNINGS
`Attorney General of the State of
`Delaware
`Delaware Department of Justice
`820 N. French Street
`Wilmington, DE 19801
`Tel: (302) 577-8600
`
`LAWRENCE G. WASDEN
`Attorney General
`State of Idaho
`700 W. Jefferson Street, Ste. 210
`P.O. Box 83720
`Boise, Idaho 83720-0010
`Tel: (208) 334-4114
`
`KWAME RAOUL
`Attorney General
`State of Illinois
`100 W. Randolph St.
`Chicago, Illinois 60601
`Tel: (312) 814-3000
`
`THEODORE E. ROKITA
`Attorney General of Indiana
`Office of the Attorney General
`200 West Washington Street,
`Room 219
`Indianapolis, IN 46204
`Tel: (317) 234-2271
`
`BRIAN E. FROSH
`Attorney General of Maryland
`200 Saint Paul Place
`Baltimore, Maryland 21202
`Tel: (410) 576-6300
`
`MAURA HEALEY
`Attorney General of Massachusetts
`One Ashburton Place
`Boston, MA 02108
`Tel: (617) 727-2200
`
`DANA NESSEL
`Michigan Attorney General
`P.O. Box 30212
`Lansing, Michigan 48909
`Tel: (517) 335-3977
`
`KEITH ELLISON
`Attorney General
`State of Minnesota
`102 State Capitol
`75 Rev. Dr. Martin Luther King Jr.
`Blvd.
`St. Paul, MN 55155
`Tel: (651) 296-3353
`
`

`

`Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 4 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`DOUGLAS J. PETERSON
`Attorney General
`State of Nebraska
`2115 State Capitol
`Lincoln, NE 68509
`Tel: (402) 471-3811
`
`AARON D. FORD
`Attorney General of Nevada
`100 North Carson Street
`Carson City, NV 89701
`Tel: (775) 684-1100
`
`JOHN M. FORMELLA
`New Hampshire Attorney General
`N.H. Dept. of Justice
`33 Capitol Street
`Concord, NH 03301
`Tel: (603) 271-3658
`
`HECTOR BALDERAS
`New Mexico Attorney General
`408 Galisteo St.
`Santa Fe, NM 87501
`Tel: (505) 490-4060
`
`LETITIA JAMES
`Attorney General of New York
`28 Liberty Street
`New York, NY 10005
`Tel: (212) 416-6312
`
`JOSHUA H. STEIN
`Attorney General
`State of North Carolina
`114 W. Edenton Street
`Raleigh, NC 27603
`Tel: (919) 716-0045
`
`WAYNE STENEHJEM
`North Dakota Attorney General
`Office of Attorney General
`1720 Burlington Drive, Suite C
`Bismarck, ND 58504-7736
`Tel: (701) 328-5570
`
`ELLEN F. ROSENBLUM
`Attorney General of Oregon
`1162 Court Street NE
`Salem, OR 97301
`Tel: (503) 378-4402
`
`PETER F. NERONHA
`Rhode Island Attorney General
`150 South Main Street,
`Providence, RI 02903
`Tel: (401) 274-4400
`
`MARK HERRING
`Attorney General of Virginia
`202 North 9th Street
`Richmond, VA 23219
`Tel: (804) 786-2071
`
`

`

`Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 5 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`PETER B. GONICK
`Deputy Solicitor General
`Office of the Attorney General
`PO Box 40100
`Olympia, WA 98504-0100
`Tel: (360) 753-6245
`
`JOSHUA L. KAUL
`Attorney General of Wisconsin
`Wisconsin Department of Justice
`Post Office Box 7857
`Madison, Wisconsin 53707-7857
`Tel: (608) 261-1221
`
`KARL A. RACINE
`Attorney General for the District of
`Columbia
`400 6th Street, NW, Suite 8100
`Washington, D.C. 20001
`Tel: (202) 727-6287
`
`LEEVIN T. CAMACHO
`Attorney General for the Territory of
`Guam
`Office of the Attorney General
`590 South Marine Corps Dr.
`Ste 901
`Tamuning, Guam 96913
`Tel: (671) 475-3324
`
`

`

`Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 6 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`TABLE OF CONTENTS
`
`TABLE OF AUTHORITIES.....................................................................................ii
`
`IDENTITY AND INTEREST OF AMICUS CURIAE............................................1
`
`SUMMARY OF ARGUMENT.................................................................................2
`
`ARGUMENT ............................................................................................................3
`
`I.
`
`II.
`
`III.
`
`IV.
`
`HEALTHCARE COMPETITION IS A MATTER OF LOCAL
`CONCERN......................................................................................................3
`
`PROVIDER CONSOLIDATION HAS RESULTED IN LARGE
`HEALTHCARE PROVIDERS WITH MARKET POWER WHO HAVE
`BEEN ABLE TO RAISE PRICES TO PAYORS AS A CONDITION FOR
`THEIR INCLUSION IN PAYORS’ NETWORKS........................................6
`
`THE DISTRICT COURT CONDUCTED A PROPER ANALYSIS AND
`CORRECTLY APPLIED THE TWO-STAGE MODEL OF
`COMPETITION TO DEFINE THE RELEVANT GEOGRAPHIC
`MARKET........................................................................................................9
`THE PURPORTED BENEFITS ARE NOT EXTRAORDINARY AND DO
`NOT OUTWEIGH THE LIKELY ANTICOMPETITIVE EFFECTS OF
`THIS PROPOSED MERGER.......................................................................12
`
`CONCLUSION ......................................................................................................18
`
`CERTIFICATE OF COUNSEL..............................................................................20
`
`CERTIFICATE OF SERVICE................................................................................21
`
`
`
`

`

`Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 7 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`TABLE OF AUTHORITIES
`
`CASES
`
`California v. Providence Group et al., Case No. 3:21-cv-07331
`
`(N.D. Cal. Sept. 21, 2021)……………………………………………….......4
`
`Commonwealth v. Geisinger Med. Ctr.,
`
`No. 1:13 CV-02647-YK (M.D. Pa. Nov. 1, 2013)…………………………..4
`
`Commonwealth v. Urology of Central Pennsylvania, Inc.,
`No. 1:11-CV01625-JEJ (M.D. Pa. Aug. 31, 2011)………………………...17
`
`FTC v. Advocate Health Care Network,
`
`841 F.3d 460, 473–74 (7th Cir.2016)……………………………………4, 11
`
`FTC v. Penn State Hershey Med. Ctr.,
`
`838 F.3d 327 (3d Cir. 2016)…………………………………………...passim
`
`F.T.C. v. H.J. Heinz Co.,
`246 F.3d 708, 721–22 (D.C. Cir. 2001) …………………………………15
`
`In the Matter of Evanston N.W. Healthcare Corp.,
`
`No. 9315, 2007 WL 2286195 at *73 (F.T.C. Aug. 6, 2007)…………15, 16
`
`Massachusetts v. Beth Israel Lahey Health, Inc.,
`
`No. 2018-3703 (Massachusetts Superior Court, November 29, 2018)……...4
`
`Medtronic, Inc. v. Lohr,
`
`518 U.S. 470, 475 (1996)……………………………………………………3
`
`New Hampshire v. Concord Hospital, Inc., et al.,
`
`No. 217-2021-cv-00225 (New Hampshire Superior Court April 20, 2021)...4
`
`People of the State of California v. Sutter Health,
`
`No. CGC 18-565398 (Cal. App. S.F. Ct., 2021)…………………………4, 8
`
`
`
`

`

`Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 8 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`St. Alphonsus Med. Ctr.-Nampa Inc. v. St. Luke's Health Sys., Ltd.,
`
`778 F.3d 775, 784 n.10 (9th Cir. 2015)………………………………....9, 16
`
`Washington v. Franciscan Health System,
`
`No. 3:17-cv-05690 (W.D. Wa. May 13, 2019)……………………………...4
`
`OTHER AUTHORITIES
`
`Antitrust Applied: Hospital Consolidation Concerns and Solutions:
`Hearings before the Subcommittee on Competition Policy, Antitrust and
`Consumer Rights, of the Senate Judiciary Committee, (May 19, 2021)
`(testimony of Professor Martin Gaynor), available at
`https://www.judiciary.senate.gov/imo/media/doc/Gaynor_Senate_Judiciary_
`Hospital_Consolidation_May_19_2021.pdf..........................................7-8, 17
`
`Areeda and Hovenkamp, ANTITRUST LAW FOURTH EDITION,
`volume 4 para 971f at 44 (2016)…………………………………………...15
`
`Arnold and Whaley, Who Pays for Health Care Costs?
`The Effect of Health Care Prices on Wages, RAND, Santa Monica, CA
`(2020)………………………………………………………………………..6
`
`Boozary, Reinhard, and Jha, The Association Between Hospital Concentration and
`Insurance Premiums in ACA Marketplaces, 38 HEALTH AFFAIRS 68, 671
`(2019)………………………………………………………………………..7
`
`Capps, Kmitch, Zabinski, and Zayats, The Continuing Saga of Hospital Merger
`Enforcement, 82 ANTITRUST L.J. 441, 484 (2019)…………………………10
`
`Charles Thompson, Penn State Health shows off newest pearl in growing
`strand of midstate hospitals, Sept. 22, 2021, available at
`https://www.pennlive.com/business/2021/09/penn-state-health-shows-off-
`newest-pearl-in-growing-strand-of-midstate-hospitals.html.........................16
`
`Examining the Impact of Health Care Consolidation:
`Hearings before the Subcommittee on Oversight and Investigations of the
`Committee on Energy and Commerce of the House of Representatives, 115th
`Congr. 99 (February 14, 2018) (Testimony of Professor Martin Gaynor)…..8
`
`iii
`
`

`

`Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 9 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`Fulton, Health Care Market Concentration Trends in the United States:
`Evidence and Policy Reponses, HEALTH AFFAIRS 36, No. 9 at 1531
`(2017)………………………………………………………………………..7
`
`Glenn Melnick and Katya Fonkych, Hospital Prices Increase in California,
`Especially Among Hospitals in the Largest Multi-hospital Systems, 53 J. of
`Healthcare Purchasing and Financing, 1-7 available at
`https://journals.sagepub.com/doi/full/10.1177/0046958016651555...............5
`
`Gudiksen et al, Preventing Anticompetitive Contracting Practices in
`Healthcare Markets, SOURCE ON HEALTHCARE PRICE AND COMPETITION at
`22 (September 2020), available at
`https://sourceonhealthcare.org/profile/preventing-anticompetitive-
`contracting-practices-in-healthcare-markets/..................................................5
`
`Heaps et al, Public Transportation in the US: A Driver of Health and Equity,
`HEALTHAFFAIRS (July 29, 2021), available at
`https://www.healthaffairs.org/do/10.1377/ hpb20210630.810356/full/……..
`
`Ioannis Pashakis, UPMC Pinnacle West Shore to finish expansion in November,
`Aug. 19, 2020, available at https://www.cpbj.com/upmc-pinnacle-west-
`shore-finish-expansion-november.................................................................17
`
`Nicolas C. Petris Center on Healthcare Markets and Consumer Welfare,
`School of Public Health, University of California, Berkeley, Consolidation
`in California’s Health Care Market 2010-2016: Impact on Prices and ACA
`Premiums, at 9 (Mar. 31, 2018), available at https://petris.org/wp-
`content/uploads/2018/03/CA-Consolidation-Full-Report_03.26.18.pdf.........5
`
`Steve Tenn, The Price Effect of Hospital Mergers:
`A Case Study of the Sutter-Summit Transaction, FEDERAL TRADE
`COMMISSION WORKING PAPER NO. 293, 1–2 (Nov. 2008)
`available at https://www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/documents/reports/price-
`effects hospitalmergers% C2%A0-case-study-sutter-summit-
`transaction/wp293_0.pdf……………………………………………………1
`
`The Impact of Hospital Consolidation on Medical Costs,
`NCCI Insights, July 11, 2018, available at
`https://www.ncci.com/Articles/Pages/II_Insights_QEB_Impact-of-Hospital-
`Consolidation-on-Medical-Costs.aspx#.......................................................13
`
`iv
`
`

`

`Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 10 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`U.S. Dep’t of Justice & FTC,
`Horizontal Merger Guidelines……………………………………………..12
`
`2 HEALTH CARE AND ANTITRUST L.,
`Analyzing hospital mergers—Unilateral effects, § 12:14 (2021)…………...8
`
`v
`
`

`

`Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 11 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`IDENTITY AND INTEREST OF AMICUS CURIAE
`
`Pursuant to Fed. R. App. P. 29(a), the Commonwealth of Pennsylvania and the State
`
`of California respectfully submit this brief, joined by the States of Colorado, Connecticut,
`
`Delaware, Idaho, Illinois, Indiana, Maryland, Massachusetts, Michigan, Minnesota,
`
`Nebraska, Nevada, New Hampshire, New Mexico, New York, North Carolina, North
`
`Dakota, Oregon, Rhode Island, Virginia, Washington, Wisconsin, the District Of
`
`Columbia, and the Territory of Guam (hereinafter States). The States have a strong interest
`
`in ensuring the availability of affordable and accessible quality healthcare for their
`
`citizens. This interest is best served by protecting vibrant competition in local healthcare
`
`markets. Mergers that substantially increase provider market share in local markets lead to
`
`increased healthcare costs in local communities and raise the overall cost of healthcare
`
`within the States.1 Moreover, the States have a responsibility for safeguarding competition
`
`in their respective state healthcare markets. This responsibility positions them uniquely to
`
`elucidate on the appropriate standards to apply in healthcare merger reviews under the
`
`federal antitrust law.
`
`1 See, e.g., Steve Tenn, The Price Effect of Hospital Mergers: A Case Study of the Sutter-
`Summit Transaction, FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION WORKING PAPER NO. 293,
`1–2 (Nov. 2008) available at
`https://www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/documents/reports/price-effects-hospitalmergers%
`C2%A0-case-study-sutter-summit-transaction/wp293_0.pdf
`1
`
`

`

`Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 12 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`SUMMARY OF ARGUMENT
`
`States plays a significant role in reviewing healthcare transactions and
`
`understanding the impact of consolidation in our states. This role uniquely situates the
`
`States to offer views on the impact of anticompetitive healthcare provider mergers and
`
`conduct within our respective states. It is this knowledge and experience in healthcare
`
`markets, which supports why the States respectfully ask this Court to affirm the district
`
`court’s opinion and uphold the preliminary injunction.
`
`The States know the importance of maintaining vibrant competitive healthcare
`
`markets to control costs while ensuring quality healthcare is affordable and available to
`
`our States’ citizens. Many of the States have seen the growth of large healthcare systems
`
`through the systematic acquisition of hospitals and physician groups, while experiencing
`
`the effects of the systems’ increased bargaining power in negotiations between insurers
`
`and providers regarding insurance plan networks offered to employers in our States. These
`
`same potential bargaining effects and concerns correctly formed the basis of the district
`
`court’s conclusion that: (1) Employers and their employees want access to healthcare that
`
`is geographically convenient to the employees; (2) For insurers to compete effectively for
`
`employers’ business, the commercial health insurers must offer provider networks of
`
`hospitals and physician groups that are located near the homes of their employees; (3)
`
`Most employees are unwilling or unable to travel great distances for medical care; and (4)
`
`The employee demand for nearby network healthcare providers enhances the bargaining
`
`2
`
`

`

`Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 13 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`power of large healthcare systems. Taken together, mergers increasing the bargaining
`
`power of large healthcare systems result in higher prices without any substantial
`
`improvements in quality for consumers.
`
` The two-stage model of competition used by Plaintiff-Appellee Federal Trade
`
`Commission (“FTC”) to assess the market impact of Defendants-Appellants’ merger
`
`properly focuses on the price effects of the increased bargaining leverage that Defendants-
`
`Appellants would gain from their merger. The localized geographic market resulting from
`
`this methodology accurately models the market dynamic that we see in our States today
`
`and is consistent with this Court’s decision in FTC v. Penn State Hershey Med. Ctr., 838
`
`F.3d 327 (3d Cir. 2016). Further, the district court properly evaluated the evidence
`
`presented regarding the harm that would be caused by the merger, and regarding any
`
`potential benefits and efficiencies, in its decision to preliminary enjoin the merger.
`
`For all these reasons, the district court reached the correct result based on the proper
`
`antitrust analysis of this merger.
`
`ARGUMENT
`
`I.
`
`HEALTHCARE COMPETITION IS A MATTER OF LOCAL CONCERN
`
`Healthcare is viewed traditionally as a local matter falling well within the police
`
`powers of the States. See, e.g., Medtronic, Inc. v. Lohr, 518 U.S. 470, 475 (1996). The
`
`“inherently local” preference for healthcare services is recognized in the federal circuit
`
`courts, which have concluded that “patients generally have a strong preference for local
`3
`
`

`

`Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 14 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`hospitals, at least for GAC [General Acute Care] services”. FTC v. Advocate Health Care
`
`Network, 841 F.3d 460, 473–74 (7th Cir. 2016); Hershey, 838 F.3d at 341.
`
`Competition is an important piece of a robust local healthcare market; thus the
`
`States frequently review healthcare transactions under both state and federal antitrust laws.
`
`Indeed, recent history has seen numerous examples of States reviewing healthcare
`
`transactions under state and federal antitrust laws.2 Through these reviews, the States
`
`have acquired a sophisticated understanding of their local hospital markets. Accordingly,
`
`we have come to see how large healthcare systems can acquire market power and
`
`successfully impose price increases on payors without risking significant patient defection
`
`to markets located farther away, because patients prefer to receive their care locally. See,
`
`
`2 See, e.g., California v. Providence Group et al., Case No. 3:21-cv-07331 (N.D. Cal.
`Sept. 21, 2021) (California Attorney General settles lawsuit brought under federal antitrust
`law against prospective merger of skilled nursing facility operators with divestiture of
`facility); People of the State of California v. Sutter Health, No. CGC 18-565398 (Cal. Sup.
`S.F. Ct. August 27, 2021) (Final Judgment entered for consent decree on antitrust action
`against Sutter Health for anticompetitive conduct in leveraging providers with market
`power to charge higher prices system-wide); New Hampshire v. Concord Hospital, Inc., et
`al., No. 217-2021-cv-00225 (New Hampshire Superior Court April 20, 2021) (New
`Hampshire Attorney General settles lawsuit brought as parens patriae on behalf of and to
`protect the health and welfare of its citizens and its general economy from proposed
`hospital acquisition.); Washington v. Franciscan Health System, No. 3:17-cv-05690 (W.D.
`Wa. May 13, 2019) (Washington Attorney General settles antitrust lawsuit challenging
`health system’s anticompetitive contract affiliation with a multi-specialty physician
`practice); Massachusetts v. Beth Israel Lahey Health, Inc., No. 2018-3703 (Massachusetts
`Superior Court, November 29, 2018) (Massachusetts Attorney General enters Assurance
`of Discontinuance addressing proposed hospital merger); Commonwealth v. Geisinger
`Med. Ctr.,, No. 1:13 CV-02647-YK (M.D. Pa. Nov. 1, 2013) (Pennsylvania Attorney
`General settles antitrust lawsuit involving health system’s acquisition of community
`hospital and its employed physicians).
`
`
`
`4
`
`

`

`Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 15 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`e.g., Tenn, The Price Effect of Hospital Mergers: A Case Study of the Sutter-Summit
`
`Transaction, , supra, at 2–3.
`
`The States have seen the consequences of acquisitions that substantially lessen
`
`competition in local provider markets. The wave of hospital consolidation over the past
`
`decades has resulted in market concentration and the creation of large healthcare systems
`
`that wield substantial market power to the detriment of patients.3 Once these systems
`
`acquire one or more providers with market power that are must-haves for insurers, not
`
`only can they charge higher prices to insurers for those providers, but also they can force
`
`the insurers to pay higher prices for all of the other provider-members of the system.
`
`These systems impose system-wide price increases through all or nothing contracting,
`
`where an insurer must contract with either every provider in a system, no matter the cost,
`
`or risk having to market economically unviable networks that lack must-have providers
`
`within that system. See, e.g., Gudiksen et al, Preventing Anticompetitive Contracting
`
`Practices in Healthcare Markets, SOURCE ON HEALTHCARE PRICE AND COMPETITION at 22
`
`(September 2020), available at https://sourceonhealthcare.org/profile/preventing-
`
`3 See, e.g., Nicolas C. Petris Center on Healthcare Markets and Consumer Welfare, School
`of Public Health, University of California, Berkeley, Consolidation in California’s Health
`Care Market 2010-2016: Impact on Prices and ACA Premiums, at 9 (Mar. 31, 2018),
`available at https://petris.org/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/CA-Consolidation-Full-
`Report_03.26.18.pdf; Glenn Melnick and Katya Fonkych, Hospital Prices Increase in
`California, Especially Among Hospitals in the Largest Multi-hospital Systems, 53 J. of
`Healthcare Purchasing and Financing, 1-7 (available at
`https://journals.sagepub.com/doi/full/10.1177/0046958016651555).
`5
`
`

`

`Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 16 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`anticompetitive-contracting-practices-in-healthcare-markets/. In addition to insurers,
`
`increased healthcare costs are also detrimental to employers: employers may need to
`
`reduce their workforce or workforce’s hours, forego expansion or expand or relocate
`
`employees to other areas with lower healthcare costs. See Arnold and Whaley, Who Pays
`
`for Health Care Costs? The Effect of Health Care Prices on Wages, RAND, Santa
`
`Monica, CA (2020).
`
`In view of those realities, the States submit that the district court properly enjoined
`
`the merger on a preliminary basis, and in particular, submit that hospitals with market
`
`power (and healthcare systems that include such hospitals) can and successfully do raise
`
`the prices charged to payors as the condition for their inclusion in payors’ networks. In
`
`evaluating the anticompetitive impact of the proposed merger, the district court properly
`
`used the two-stage model of competition to assess the anticompetitive effect of the merger
`
`as well as properly considered the prior anticompetitive conduct of the healthcare system
`
`at issue. Moreover, the district court properly found that the claimed benefits do not
`
`amount to extraordinary efficiencies that offset the likely anticompetitive effects of this
`
`hospital merger.
`
`II.
`
`PROVIDER CONSOLIDATION HAS RESULTED IN LARGE
`HEALTHCARE PROVIDERS WITH MARKET POWER WHO HAVE
`BEEN ABLE TO RAISE PRICES TO PAYORS AS A CONDITION FOR
`THEIR INCLUSION IN PAYORS’ NETWORKS
`
`There is a general correlation between market concentration, higher prices, and
`
`higher health insurance premiums. In fact, some studies have found price increases
`
`6
`
`

`

`Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 17 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`exceeding twenty percent when mergers occur in concentrated markets. E.g., Fulton,
`
`Health Care Market Concentration Trends in the United States: Evidence and Policy
`
`Reponses, HEALTH AFFAIRS 36, No. 9 at 1531 (2017). Additional research has found that
`
`hospital markets with high hospital concentrations also had higher premiums than hospital
`
`markets with low hospital concentrations. Boozary, Reinhard, and Jha, The Association
`
`Between Hospital Concentration and Insurance Premiums in ACA Marketplaces, 38
`
`HEALTH AFFAIRS 68, 671 (2019). Thus, hospitals facing less competition have an ability
`
`to charge higher prices to private payors, without accompanying them with gains in
`
`efficiency or quality. Further, lack of competition can harm the quality of care that is
`
`provided. For example, Professor Gaynor’s testimony points to several studies involving
`
`cardiac care. One study shows that risk-adjusted one year mortality for Medicare heart
`
`attack (acute myocardial infarction, or AMI) patients is significantly higher in more
`
`concentrated markets. Other studies found that hospital mergers in New York state and
`
`California led to increases in mortality for patients suffering from heart attacks, failure or
`
`heart disease. Hospital market concentration is strongly associated with multiple measures
`
`of negative patient satisfaction. See Antitrust Applied: Hospital Consolidation Concerns
`
`and Solutions: Hearings before the Subcommittee on Competition Policy, Antitrust and
`
`Consumer Rights, of the Senate Judiciary Committee, 11-12 (May 19, 2021) (testimony of
`
`Professor Martin Gaynor), available at
`
`7
`
`

`

`Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 18 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`https://www.judiciary.senate.gov/imo/media/doc/Gaynor_Senate_Judiciary_Hospital_Con
`
`solidation_May_19_2021.pdf.
`
`Once a provider has obtained market power, it may be incentivized to maintain or
`
`enhance it, leading to an increased risk of anticompetitive conduct. Dominant providers
`
`can exert market power through various contracting provisions with insurers. For
`
`example, a dominant health system can require that insurers contract with all the dominant
`
`system’s hospitals and physicians in order to get access to any part of the system. They
`
`can also demand higher payment rates for the entire system. See People of the State of
`
`California v. Sutter Health, No. CGC 18-565398 (Cal. Sup. S.F. Ct. August 27, 2021)
`
`(court granting final judgment in settlement of claims that such anticompetitive conduct
`
`led to higher prices); see also 2 HEALTH CARE AND ANTITRUST L., Analyzing hospital
`
`mergers—Unilateral effects, § 12:14 (2021) (discussing negotiation process between
`
`commercial health plans and providers generally and noting the phenomenon of “must
`
`have” providers for commercially viable network plans); cf. Horizontal Merger Guidelines
`
`§ 6.2 (2010) (“A merger between two competing sellers prevents buyers from playing
`
`those sellers off against each other in negotiations. This alone can significantly enhance
`
`the ability and incentive of the merged entity to obtain a result more favorable to it . . .”).
`
`Quality can also be impacted negatively in concentrated markets as hospitals face
`
`less competition. See Examining the Impact of Health Care Consolidation: Hearings
`
`before the Subcommittee on Oversight and Investigations of the Committee on Energy
`
`8
`
`

`

`Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 19 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`and Commerce of the House of Representatives, 115th Cong. 99 (February 14, 2018)
`
`(Testimony of Professor Martin Gaynor).
`
`III. THE DISTRICT COURT CONDUCTED A PROPER ANALYSIS AND
`CORRECTLY APPLIED THE TWO-STAGE MODEL OF COMPETITION
`TO DEFINE THE RELEVANT GEOGRAPHIC MARKET
`
`The district court properly defined the relevant geographic market as Bergen
`
`County. Op. 35-36. The States urge this Court to sustain the district court’s application of
`
`the two-stage model of competition to define the relevant geographic market and reject the
`
`Appellants’ argument that price discrimination must also be used. Hospital. Brief. 25-32.
`
`In reaching the decision, the district court properly defined the relevant geographic
`
`market as the county for the purpose of assessing the competitive effects of this merger.
`
`Courts commonly use the “hypothetical monopolist test” to define a relevant geographic
`
`market for examining the effects of a merger. See Hershey, 838 F.3d at 342 (“A common
`
`method employed by courts and the FTC to determine the relevant geographic market is
`
`the hypothetical monopolist test”—“if a hypothetical monopolist could impose a small but
`
`significant non-transitory increase in price (‘SSNIP’) in the proposed market, the market is
`
`properly defined.”). Changes in payor provider bargaining positions, as the hypothetical
`
`monopolist test measures, properly predict the geographic area where a merger may have
`
`anticompetitive effects. St. Alphonsus Med. Ctr.-Nampa Inc. v. St. Luke's Health Sys., Ltd.,
`
`778 F.3d 775, 784 n.10 (9th Cir. 2015). The district court properly followed this approach,
`
`9
`
`

`

`Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 20 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`using the two-stage model of competition in defining the relevant geographic market as
`
`Bergen County, and the area in which a hypothetical monopolist could raise prices for
`
`hospital services.
`
`The two-stage model of competition looks at the impact on payors and patients and
`
`recognizes that patient non-price preferences are important to the bargaining on price and
`
`access between insurers and providers. See, e.g., Hershey, 838 F.3d at 342; see also
`
`Capps, Kmitch, Zabinski, and Zayats, The Continuing Saga of Hospital Merger
`
`Enforcement, 82 ANTITRUST L.J. 441, 484 (2019) (noting appellate courts’ “consistent and
`
`strong recognition” of the two-stage model). In the first stage of competition, hospitals
`
`compete to be included in an insurance plan’s hospital network based on price, quality,
`
`and accessibility. In the second stage, patients choose hospitals within a provider network
`
`put together by their insurers based on non-price considerations such as ease of access.
`
`See, Hershey, 838 F.3d at 342. Patients are relevant to the analysis to the extent that their
`
`behavior affects the relative bargaining positions of insurers and hospitals as they
`
`negotiate rates. Id. Patients, in large part, do not feel the impact of price increases;
`
`insurers do. It is not until insurers pass on those price increases to patients in the form of
`
`higher premiums that patients feel the impact of the price increases. Even then those
`
`increases will be spread among many insured patients. Id. Looking only at insurers or
`
`only at patients in isolation will not give an accurate picture of a hospital market, you have
`
`to look at them in combination.
`
`10
`
`

`

`Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 21 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`Under the two-stage model, the relevant geographic market accounts for patient
`
`preferences. It also reflects that the more options insurers have for choosing among
`
`providers in building a network that caters to patient preferences, the more insurers can
`
`obtain a better price. Conversely, the fewer the options insurers have in choosing among
`
`providers to cater to patient preferences, the more the remaining providers can command a
`
`higher price. Under the two-stage model, providers with market power, can raise prices
`
`for insurers without having to price discriminate between the substantial number of
`
`patients living close by those providers versus those living farther away. This holds true
`
`even if there are a substantial number of patients who travel to those hospitals from farther
`
`away and have other options. See, e.g., Hershey, 838 F.3d at 339–41.
`
`In applying the two-stage model, the district court correctly focused on insurer
`
`testimony that insurers could not successfully market health plans in Bergen County
`
`without access to Bergen County hospitals. The insurers recognized that individuals
`
`prefer to receive care close to home and that they must consider the preferences of Bergen
`
`County residents in the construction of their networks (Op. 38-40). See Hershey, 838 F.3d
`
`at 352 (crediting “extensive testimony by payors that ‘there would be no network’ without
`
`Hershey and Pinnacle.”); Advocate, 841 F.3d at 460, 464, 471 (“Insured patients are
`
`usually not sensitive to retail hospital prices, while insurers respond to both prices and
`
`patient preferences…”).
`
`11
`
`

`

`Case: 21-2603 Document: 91 Page: 22 Date Filed: 11/05/2021
`
`The district court also correctly factored in the prior history of the acquiring
`
`healthcare system in successfully implem

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket