throbber
Case 3:17-md-02773-JSC Document 914 Filed 01/06/23 Page 1 of 37
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
`
`NORTHERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA
`
`IN RE: QUALCOMM ANTITRUST
`LITIGATION
`
`Case No. 17-md-02773-JSC
`
`
`ORDER REGARDING MOTION TO
`DISMISS
`
`Re: Dkt. No. 895
`
`
`
`Cellphones and tablets connect us to one another. To do so, devices rely on hardware
`
`(known as modem chips) and critical patented technologies. Qualcomm is a successful company
`
`in these two distinct, yet related fields: modem chip manufacturing and cellular patent licensing.
`
`Six years ago, the Federal Trade Commission brought an antitrust action against Qualcomm. Not
`
`long after, Plaintiffs—a series of consumers—sued Qualcomm as well. These separate suits raised
`
`similar objections. Each alleged Qualcomm uses its position at the confluence between chip
`
`manufacturing and patent licensing to stifle competition. Plaintiffs sought to represent millions of
`
`cellular device consumers who, they allege, overpaid due to Qualcomm’s conduct.
`
`The FTC action led the way. After a bench trial, the district court found Qualcomm
`
`violated federal antitrust law. The Ninth Circuit reversed that decision in FTC v. Qualcomm Inc.,
`
`969 F.3d 974 (9th Cir. 2020), and remanded Plaintiffs’ parallel consumer action to this Court.
`
`Stromberg v. Qualcomm Inc., 14 F.4th 1059, 1075 (9th Cir. 2021). After remand, Plaintiffs filed
`
`an amended complaint, asserting only violations of California law and on behalf of only California
`
`consumers. Qualcomm moves to dismiss. The question before this Court is whether Plaintiffs’
`
`complaint survives FTC v. Qualcomm and states a claim under California law.
`
`The answer is no, but only in part. Plaintiffs’ tying theory is not viable under current
`
`California law. But California law and stare decisis do not require the Court to dismiss the
`
`exclusive dealing theory on a 12(b)(6) motion. Plaintiffs’ derivative unfair competition claim also
`
`survives in part. So, the Court GRANTS in part and DENIES in part Defendant’s motion to
`
`dismiss.
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`Northern District of California
`
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 3:17-md-02773-JSC Document 914 Filed 01/06/23 Page 2 of 37
`
`
`
`I.
`
`Complaint Allegations
`
`A. Industry Background
`
`
`
`1.
`
`Modem Chips
`
`BACKGROUND
`
`Every smartphone, tablet, and other cellular device contains a piece of equipment called a
`
`modem chip. (Dkt. No. 899 ¶ 8.)1 The modem chip allows a device to connect and communicate
`
`with wireless cellular networks—such as those controlled by AT&T, Verizon and Sprint in the
`
`United States. (Id.) A device without a modem chip would be unable to make calls and could not
`
`send or receive data outside the presence of a Wi-Fi access point. (Id. ¶ 32.) In other words, a
`
`smartphone without a modem chip is not much of a phone at all. (Id. ¶ 8.)
`
`
`
`2.
`
`Cellular Network Standards and Standard Setting Organizations
`
`Cellular network “standards” govern how data moves from device to device across the
`
`network. To make those vital connections—between a device and a network—the device’s
`
`modem chip must be compatible with a cellular network’s particular technical standard. (Id. ¶ 33.)
`
`
`
`
`
`a.
`
`Standard Setting Organizations
`
`For decades, telecommunications industry participants and government agencies have
`
`negotiated, adopted, and implemented common “communications standards.” (Id. ¶ 9.) By
`
`sharing common blueprints, the industry allowed device and network interoperability. (Id.) Thus,
`
`an average consumer can buy a phone from their preferred device manufacturer (like Apple or
`
`Samsung) and use the phone with their chosen network carrier (such as Verizon or Sprint) because
`
`many network carriers use a common communications standard and the device contains a modem
`
`chip that can communicate with the common standard. (Id.)
`
`“Standard setting organizations” or “SSOs” develop these standards. (Id. ¶ 10.) SSOs
`
`include telecommunications technology companies, device suppliers and manufacturers, and
`
`government agencies. (Id. ¶ 38.) The Telecommunications Industry Association is the primary
`
`standard setting organization for wireless communications in the United States. (Id.) The
`
`
`1 Record citations are to material in the Electronic Case File (“ECF”); pinpoint citations are to the
`ECF-generated page numbers at the top of the documents.
`2
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`Northern District of California
`
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 3:17-md-02773-JSC Document 914 Filed 01/06/23 Page 3 of 37
`
`
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`European Telecommunications Standards Institute, an organization based in France, focuses on
`
`producing global communication standards. (Id.) Over the past four decades, these and other
`
`SSOs developed three broad “generations” of communications standards relevant here—second-
`
`generation (“2G”), third-generation (“3G”), and fourth-generation (“4G”) standards. (Id.)
`
`
`
`
`
`b.
`
`Particular Communications Standards
`
`A “generation” can comprise multiple specific standards with similar capabilities. (Id.)
`
`For example, the industry developed 2G cellular standards in the early 1990s. (Id. ¶ 39.) 2G
`
`communications standards support digital transmission of voice calls. The leading 2G standards
`
`are the Global System for Mobile Communications (“GSM”) and Code Division Multiple Access
`
`(“2G-CDMA”). (Id.) AT&T and T-Mobile chose to operate GSM networks. By contrast,
`
`Verizon and Sprint operated 2G-CDMA networks. (Id.)
`
`The 3G series, developed in the late 1990s, had two leading standards as well. (Id. ¶ 40.)
`
`GSM 2G networks like AT&T and T-Mobile implemented the Universal Mobile
`
`Telecommunications System (“UMTS”), which incorporated a technology known as wideband
`
`CDMA (“WCDMA”). (Id.) The 2G-CDMA operators, such as Verizon and Sprint, migrated to
`
`the third-generation CDMA standard (“3G-CDMA”). (Id.) Between 2000 and 2010, Verizon and
`
`Sprint invested over $57 billion in their CDMA-based networks. (Id. ¶ 176.)
`
`The 4G series of standards were first introduced in 2009. (Id. ¶ 41.) 4G standards allow
`
`for higher data-transmission speeds than 3G standards. (Id.) Most major operators chose a 4G
`
`standard known as Long-Term-Evolution (“LTE”). (Id.) When initially deployed, 4G-LTE
`
`covered data services in urban markets. (Id. ¶ 178.) But customers still required a chip
`
`compatible with 3G-CDMA or 3G-WCDMA to make voice calls. (Id.) Some individual chips,
`
`known as “multi-mode chips,” operate with multiple standards to solve this dilemma. (Id. ¶ 33.)
`
`3.
`
`Standard Essential Patents
`
`A “standard” is a collection of technologies. Some technologies in the standard are
`
`patented, others are not. As the discussion above illustrates, each standard “generation” lasts for
`
`about a decade. When a standard setting organization incorporates a new technology into a new
`
`standard, access to the technology becomes vital to the domestic and international
`
`3
`
`Northern District of California
`
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 3:17-md-02773-JSC Document 914 Filed 01/06/23 Page 4 of 37
`
`
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`telecommunications infrastructure. (Id. ¶ 11.) Thus, by creating a set of technologies to comprise
`
`a “standard,” the standard setters effectively pick market winners and losers for a generation of
`
`cellular technology. (Id. ¶ 10.) The winners—patents protecting technologies vital to a
`
`communications standard—are known as standard essential patents (“SEPs”). (Id. ¶ 11.)
`
`Standard essential patent holders reap large financial benefits because industry participants
`
`selling devices or technologies compliant with the relevant standard must pay the essential patent
`
`holder licensing and royalty fees—or risk suit for patent infringement. (Id.) If unchecked, a
`
`standard essential patent holder could demand excessive licensing and royalty fees once their
`
`protected technology is locked into the communications standard. (Id.) This maneuver is known
`
`as a “patent hold up.” (Id. ¶ 43.)
`
`Standard setting organizations established rules to prohibit patent hold ups. (Id. ¶ 12.) To
`
`participate in the standard setting process, industry participants must disclose all patents they hold
`
`on technologies under consideration for incorporation into a standard. (Id. ¶ 45.) Patent holders
`
`must agree—as an express condition for incorporation into the standard—to license the
`
`technology to other industry participants on fair, reasonable, and non-discriminatory (“FRAND”)
`
`terms. (Id.) Absent such a promise, the standard setters will design around the claimed
`
`“essential” patent at issue. (Id.)
`
`B. Qualcomm’s Market Position
`
` Qualcomm, located in San Diego, California, develops, designs, licenses, and markets
`
`digital communications products and services through two wholly owned subsidiaries—
`
`Qualcomm Technology Licensing and Qualcomm CDMA Technologies. (Id. ¶ 27.) Qualcomm
`
`Technology Licensing licenses patents and other intellectual property rights from Qualcomm’s
`
`intellectual portfolio. (Id.) Qualcomm CDMA Technologies handles equipment sales including
`
`the sale of modem chips to device manufacturers. (Id.)
`
`
`
`1.
`
`Qualcomm’s Patent Licensing Business
`
`“As an early developer of cellular technology, Qualcomm holds patents on technologies
`
`that were incorporated into virtually every relevant cellular standard adopted during the period
`
`relevant to this litigation,” including the CDMA, WCDMA/UMTS, and LTE standards. (Id.
`
`4
`
`Northern District of California
`
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 3:17-md-02773-JSC Document 914 Filed 01/06/23 Page 5 of 37
`
`
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`¶¶ 13, 36.) In the 2G era, Qualcomm’s SEP portfolio comprised a significant portion of the
`
`overall 2G-CDMA standard. (Id. ¶ 39.) Qualcomm’s SEP market-share diminished during the 3G
`
`era relative to the 2G era. (Id. ¶ 40.) And Qualcomm’s share of 4G-LTE SEPs is “roughly
`
`equivalent to that of other industry competitors.” (Id. ¶ 41.) “One study of declared LTE SEPs
`
`found that Qualcomm had a 13% share of ‘highly novel’ essential LTE patents, compared to 19%
`
`for Nokia, 12% for Ericsson, and 12% for Samsung.” (Id.)
`
`Qualcomm promised standard setting organizations it would license its cellular SEPs for
`
`2G, 3G, and 4G standards on FRAND terms. (Id. ¶ 50.) For example, the European
`
`Telecommunications Standards Institute requires participants to declare any essential patents
`
`within a proposed standard and mandates a commitment to grant irrevocable patent licenses on
`
`FRAND terms. (Id. ¶ 51.) Qualcomm declared over 30,000 global assets as essential intellectual
`
`property rights, and told the European Telecommunications Standards Institute it was “prepared to
`
`grant irrevocable licenses” under its policies. (Id.) But, as discussed in more detail below,
`
`Plaintiffs allege Qualcomm broke its promises to the various SSOs and refused to license its SEPs
`
`to rival chip manufacturers. (Id. ¶ 53.)
`
`Instead, Qualcomm licensed its SEP portfolio to device manufacturers—also known as
`
`“original equipment manufacturers” or “OEMs.” (Id. ¶ 60.) Qualcomm charged device
`
`manufacturers SEP royalties based on the price of an entire finished device. (Id. ¶ 18.) For
`
`example, an iPhone’s price dictates Qualcomm’s royalty for the SEP license Qualcomm granted to
`
`Apple. (Id.) Thus, Qualcomm’s royalty increased as the device price went up, even if Apple
`
`charged more for an iPhone model based on features—like a superior camera or increased
`
`storage—unrelated to Qualcomm’s protected technologies. (Id.)
`
`These licensing agreements were lucrative. (Id. ¶ 57.) During the class period,
`
`Qualcomm charged device manufactures up to a 5% royalty rate on the final device (also known
`
`as “handset”) price. (Id. ¶ 194.) Thus, if Apple sold an iPhone for $600, Qualcomm received a
`
`$30 payment for each sale. While license agreements comprised a smaller share of Qualcomm’s
`
`gross revenue than chip sales, the licensing business accounts for most of Qualcomm’s net profits.
`
`(Id.) In 2013 and 2014, Qualcomm collected licensing revenues of approximately $7.8 billion.
`
`5
`
`Northern District of California
`
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 3:17-md-02773-JSC Document 914 Filed 01/06/23 Page 6 of 37
`
`
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`(Id. ¶ 196.) Four companies with similar SEP portfolios—Alcatel-Lucent, Ericsson, InterDigital,
`
`and Nokia—combined for a total of $2.7 billion in licensing revenue over the same period. (Id.)
`
`2.
`
`Qualcomm’s Chip Business
`
`
`
`Qualcomm’s chip business manufactures modem chips compliant with 2G-CDMA, 3G-
`
`CDMA, UMTS, and LTE standards. (Id. ¶ 54.) During the class period, Qualcomm had
`
`monopoly power in two types of chips—CDMA chips and premium LTE chips. (Id.)
`
`
`
`
`
`a.
`
`CDMA Chips
`
`According to the complaint, Qualcomm controlled over 90% market share for CDMA chip
`
`sales between 2011 and 2018. (Id. ¶ 185.) By the end of the class period in 2018, Qualcomm held
`
`99% CDMA chip market share. (Id.) As discussed above, carriers like Verizon and Sprint
`
`invested billions of dollars in CDMA networks between 2000 and 2010. (Id. ¶ 176.) But CDMA
`
`networks remain relevant even today—when the primary data service used is 4G-LTE—because
`
`customers require backwards compatible devices. (Id. ¶ 180.)
`
`
`
`
`
`b.
`
`Premium LTE Chips
`
`Qualcomm also has monopoly power in the manufacturing and sale of 4G-LTE chips. (Id.
`
`¶ 191.) LTE chips are used in premium devices—those sold for over $300 through 2012 and over
`
`$400 from 2013 onwards. (Id.) From 2011 to 2015, Qualcomm had 90% or more of the market
`
`share in “Premium LTE.” (Id.) From 2016 to 2018, “Intel slowly began to gain market share, but
`
`Qualcomm continued to hold a significant majority of the Premium LTE market share.” (Id.)
`
`
`
`
`
`c.
`
`Modem Chip Competitors
`
`Though Plaintiffs often refer to “competitors” or “rival chipmakers,” the SAC never
`
`explicitly defines Qualcomm’s chip-manufacturing competitors. Intel is the primary chip-
`
`manufacturing competitor referenced in the SAC. In 2017, Intel began supplying a portion of the
`
`chips Apple incorporates in the iPhone 7. (Id. ¶ 145.) To bolster its CDMA capabilities for the
`
`iPhone 7 deal, Intel acquired VIA Telecom—which, presumably had some CDMA capabilities.
`
`(Id. ¶ 165.) Intel announced it would no longer manufacture modem chipsets in 2019—after the
`
`class period ended. (Id. ¶ 145.) The SAC also references MediaTek, Samsung Electronics, and
`
`Broadcom. (Id. ¶¶ 98, 101, 121.)
`
`6
`
`Northern District of California
`
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 3:17-md-02773-JSC Document 914 Filed 01/06/23 Page 7 of 37
`
`
`
`C. Qualcomm’s Business Practices
`
`The interplay between Qualcomm’s patent licensing business and Qualcomm’s chip sale
`
`business is the crux of this case. Plaintiffs allege Qualcomm engaged in three connected business
`
`practices: (1) Qualcomm refused to license its cellular SEPs to other chip manufacturers; (2)
`
`Qualcomm’s “no license, no chips” policy denied OEMs access to chips unless the OEMs
`
`purchased Qualcomm’s cellular SEP license for an unreasonably high price and gave up the right
`
`to challenge Qualcomm’s SEPs; and (3) Qualcomm made “exclusive dealing” arrangements with
`
`OEMs to maintain its chip market monopoly.
`
`
`
`1.
`
`Qualcomm and Other Chip Manufacturers (Competitors)
`
`Qualcomm refused to sell “exhaustive”2 SEP licenses to competing modem chip
`
`manufacturers. (Id. ¶ 120.) Instead of licensing to rival chip manufacturers,3 Qualcomm only
`
`licensed its SEPs at the OEM level (e.g., to companies like Apple) or to OEMs’ contract
`
`manufacturers (e.g., Foxconn). (Id. ¶¶ 68, 132.) Plaintiffs argue Qualcomm’s policy violated
`
`Qualcomm’s FRAND obligations, which required Qualcomm to license its cellular SEPs to OEMs
`
`as well as competing chip suppliers on FRAND terms.4 (Id. ¶ 97.)
`
`According to Qualcomm’s rivals, Qualcomm’s refusal to sell an exhaustive license for
`
`Qualcomm’s SEPs put other industry players at a competitive disadvantage. (Id. ¶ 97.) For
`
`
`2 An “exhaustive” license refers to patent exhaustion. If Qualcomm granted an “exhaustive”
`cellular SEP license to a competitor—for example, Intel—Intel could then sell a chip with that
`technology to Apple. (Id. ¶ 119.) That sale might “exhaust” Qualcomm’s rights in the SEP,
`meaning Qualcomm could not sue Apple for patent infringement when Apple uses the Intel chip
`(and Qualcomm’s SEP technology) in an Apple device. (Id.) In that world, Apple would have no
`incentive to purchase an SEP license from Qualcomm or pay Qualcomm a royalty.
`
` 3
`
` While Qualcomm refused to grant its rivals exhaustive licenses, Qualcomm did allow its rivals to
`practice some of its SEPs. See F.T.C. v. Qualcomm Inc., 969 F.3d 974, 984 (9th Cir. 2020). These
`deals with competitors were known as “CDMA ASIC Agreements.” Id. In short, Qualcomm
`promised not to assert its patents against its rivals. Id. In exchange, rivals agreed to sell chips
`only to OEMs that buy Qualcomm SEP licenses. Id. Thus, competitors could practice
`Qualcomm’s patents royalty free but were forced to report details of chip supply agreements with
`OEMs. Id. at 985.
`
` 4
`
` For example, if a chip a rival can sell a chip for $5.00, Qualcomm “couldn’t charge a $10.00
`royalty” for the SEP rights because it might be difficult to convince a court $10.00 is a fair
`royalty. But, if the SEP license is sold only to OEMs for a 5% royalty on the entire price of the
`finished device, Qualcomm can obtain $30.00 on a $600 device. (Dkt. No. 899 ¶ 120.)
`7
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`Northern District of California
`
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 3:17-md-02773-JSC Document 914 Filed 01/06/23 Page 8 of 37
`
`
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`example, a Samsung employee stated “[i]f we didn’t get the license I believe there would be the
`
`IP-related risk, meaning that Qualcomm could make an assertion relating to their IP to Samsung
`
`Electronics as well as customers of modem chips of Samsung Electronics.” (Id. ¶ 98.) A
`
`MediaTek employee testified customers “were telling us that we needed a license from Qualcomm
`
`. . . Because I think there was this belief in the industry, that if they didn’t – if we didn’t have a
`
`license from Qualcomm, they wouldn’t be able to procure and sell products with our chips in
`
`them.” (Id. ¶ 101.)
`
`
`
`2.
`
`Qualcomm and OEMs (Customers)
`
` Plaintiffs allege Qualcomm engaged in two related business practices with OEMs. First,
`
`Qualcomm maintained a “no license, no chips” policy towards OEMs. Second, Qualcomm
`
`offered OEMs vast financial “rebates” if OEMs agreed to purchase Qualcomm chips on an
`
`exclusive basis.
`
`a.
`
`“No License, No Chips”
`
`
`
`Qualcomm’s FRAND commitments required Qualcomm to license its cellular SEPs to
`
`OEMs on FRAND terms. (Id. ¶ 52.) But Plaintiffs allege Qualcomm violated this promise too.
`
`(Id. ¶ 60.) Instead, Qualcomm “refused to supply cellular handset OEMs with CDMA and
`
`Premium LTE chips unless the OEM agrees to take out a separate license to all of Qualcomm’s
`
`cellular SEPs on Qualcomm’s preferred terms.” (Id. ¶ 59.) According to Plaintiffs, those terms
`
`were highly prejudicial to licensees and inconsistent with Qualcomm’s FRAND promises. (Id.)
`
`As discussed above, the SEP licenses were very profitable for Qualcomm. OEMs paid a
`
`royalty based on the price of the entire finished device, rather than the price of the chip. (Id. ¶ 60.)
`
`Thus, even if an OEM sold a device with a non-Qualcomm-manufactured chip, Qualcomm still
`
`collects a royalty payment for the SEP rights based on the price of the entire finished handset. (Id.)
`
`OEMs also agreed to forgo litigation regarding Qualcomm’s patents or license terms. (Id.)
`
`This condition—known as “no license, no chips”—is “unique” in the industry. (Id. ¶ 89.)
`
`According to Plaintiffs, OEMs faced a Hobson’s choice. OEMs need chips to sell mobile phones.
`
`(Id. ¶¶ 80–81.) And Qualcomm has monopoly power in the vital CDMA and Premium LTE chip
`
`markets. (Id.) If OEMs refused to pay Qualcomm’s SEP royalty rates—which exceeded the
`
`8
`
`Northern District of California
`
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 3:17-md-02773-JSC Document 914 Filed 01/06/23 Page 9 of 37
`
`
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`FRAND rates—Qualcomm would put the OEMs chip supply in “peril.” (Id. ¶ 81.) Thus,
`
`Qualcomm had OEMs “over a barrel.” (Id. ¶¶ 80–81.) No license, no chips. No chips, no
`
`business. So, the OEMs acquiesced to SEP licensing rates they considered unfair. (Id.) And the
`
`OEMs agreed not to challenge those above-FRAND rates (or the SEPs validity) through litigation.
`
`(Id. ¶ 60.) Plaintiffs call the difference between a FRAND SEP royalty rate and Qualcomm’s
`
`royalty rate “an added surcharge” which the OEM must pay to ensure continued access to modem
`
`chips. (Id. ¶ 199.) Thus, Qualcomm’s power in the chipset market protected its ability to charge
`
`above-FRAND rates on the SEP licenses.
`
`Qualcomm explicitly acknowledged that its chip business monopoly protected its licensing
`
`profits. (Id. ¶ 85.) For example, Qualcomm’s Vice President of Finance wrote that “there is a
`
`high correlation between our modem (chip) share and licensing compliance and royalty
`
`sustainability.” (Id.) He called it “CRITICAL” that Qualcomm maintain its high market share in
`
`the modem chip business to protect the high-profit licensing business. (Id.)
`
`b.
`
`Exclusive Chip-Supply Deals
`
`Qualcomm’s efforts to protect that modem chip market share are the final piece of the
`
`puzzle. Aside from refusing to grant competitors exhaustive licenses to cellular SEPs, Qualcomm
`
`also offered exclusive dealing arrangements to key OEM customers. The SAC lists numerous
`
`OEMs that bought between 85% and 100% of their chipsets from Qualcomm in exchange for
`
`“incentives” or “reduced royalties.” (Id. ¶ 72.) But the exclusive dealing allegations largely focus
`
`on Qualcomm’s relationship with Apple. (See id. ¶¶ 129–169.)
`
`Apple sells multiple devices that use modem chips, such as iPhones and iPads. (Id. ¶ 129.)
`
`According to the complaint, Apple is one of the largest purchasers of modem chips in the world.
`
`(Id.) “Apple is a particularly important OEM from the perspective of a nascent [chip] supplier”
`
`because working with Apple makes that supplier more competitive with other OEMs. (Id. ¶ 143.)
`
`Apple employs contract manufacturers to assemble the iPhones and iPads. (Id. ¶ 131.) The
`
`contract manufacturers pay the SEP license royalties to Qualcomm and then pass that cost along to
`
`Apple. (Id.)
`
`In 2007, Qualcomm and Apple entered a “Marketing Incentive Agreement.” (Id. ¶ 134.)
`
`9
`
`Northern District of California
`
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 3:17-md-02773-JSC Document 914 Filed 01/06/23 Page 10 of 37
`
`
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`Under that agreement, Qualcomm paid Apple “marketing incentives” and Apple agreed not to
`
`incorporate a proposed 4G WiMax Cellular standard that Intel advocated and Qualcomm opposed.
`
`(Id.) This led to widespread adoption of 4G LTE, which contains a higher percentage of
`
`Qualcomm’s patents and a lower percentage of Intel’s patents than 4G WiMax. (Id.)
`
`In 2009, Apple and Qualcomm entered into a chip supply agreement. (Id. ¶ 135.) Under a
`
`“Strategic Terms Agreement,” Qualcomm supplied chips and software to Apple. (Id.) Qualcomm
`
`also “capped its liability for failure to supply” chips and retained a unilateral right to terminate its
`
`obligations to Apple and its contract manufacturers. (Id.)
`
`According to Plaintiffs, Qualcomm and Apple then entered into “de facto exclusive dealing
`
`contracts” that foreclosed Qualcomm’s competitors from gaining modem chip business with
`
`Apple. (Id. ¶¶ 136, 143.) For example, Apple and Qualcomm negotiated and agreed upon a
`
`“Transition Agreement” in 2011. (Id. ¶ 137.) Under that agreement, Qualcomm promised
`
`substantial incentive payments to Apple. (Id.) In exchange, Apple agreed to use Qualcomm chips
`
`exclusively in all new iPhone and iPad models. (Id.) Apple also promised not to challenge
`
`Qualcomm over intellectual property disputes. (Id.)
`
`The First Amended Transition Agreement—effective 2013 to 2016—continued the
`
`exclusivity arrangement and included a condition that Apple could not initiate or induce another to
`
`initiate litigation based on Qualcomm’s failure to offer licenses on FRAND terms. (Id. ¶ 138.)
`
`Qualcomm also agreed to make “separate substantial incentive payments to Apple so long as
`
`Apple exclusively sourced chips from Qualcomm.” (Id.) But if Apple violated that exclusivity
`
`and used non-Qualcomm chips in a device, Apple would forfeit past and future incentive
`
`payments. (Id.) The parties also formed a “Business Cooperation and Patent Agreement
`
`(“BCPA”) in 2013. (Id. ¶ 139.) In the BCPA, Qualcomm agreed to continue the “marketing
`
`incentive payments” first negotiated in 2009. (Id.)
`
`According to Plaintiffs, the 2011 and 2013 agreements were “intended by Qualcomm to
`
`be, de facto exclusive deals that were as effective as express purchase requirements and essentially
`
`foreclosed Qualcomm’s competitors from gaining chip business at Apple.” (Id. ¶ 141.) Although
`
`Apple had “interest in developing and working with additional suppliers of chips,” the penalties
`
`10
`
`Northern District of California
`
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 3:17-md-02773-JSC Document 914 Filed 01/06/23 Page 11 of 37
`
`
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`Apple would face under its agreements with Qualcomm allegedly deterred Apple from using other
`
`suppliers. (Id.) According to Plaintiffs, the penalties were sufficiently large such that—if they
`
`were attributed as discounts to the price of Qualcomm’s chips—the resulting price for chips would
`
`be below Qualcomm’s cost to produce the chips. (Id.)
`
`As a result of these agreements, Apple sourced chips exclusively from Qualcomm for all
`
`new iPad and iPhone products launched between October 2011 and September 2016. (Id. ¶ 142.)
`
`According to the complaint, Qualcomm’s exclusive deal with Apple “prevented Qualcomm’s
`
`competitors from attaining [the benefits of working with Apple] and foreclosed a substantial share
`
`of the market for Premium LTE chips.” (Id. ¶ 144.) Intel eventually won Apple’s business in 2017
`
`for the iPhone 7. (Id. ¶ 145.) But Plaintiffs allege Qualcomm’s conduct “locked Intel out of
`
`Apple” for the four years prior to that agreement. (Id. ¶ 145.)
`
`3.
`
`Summary
`
`Plaintiffs’ allegations sit at the intersection of antitrust and patent law. Qualcomm had a
`
`monopoly in the market for CDMA and Premium-LTE Chips. And Qualcomm had critical SEPs
`
`necessary to participate in the cellular telecommunications industry. If an OEM wanted to use
`
`chips, that OEM had to buy a license from Qualcomm or risk patent litigation. Typically, SSOs
`
`require SEP holders to give licenses to rivals and customers at FRAND rates. But Qualcomm
`
`ignored those obligations.
`
`Instead, Qualcomm refused to license its chip-manufacturing competitors outright and
`
`offered SEP licenses to OEMs for prices far greater than it could have charged rival chip makers.
`
`Then, under its “no license, no chips” policy, Qualcomm refused to sell OEMs chips unless the
`
`OEMs bought a separate (but related) product—the SEP license—at the inflated rate and agreed
`
`not to challenge those rates or patents via litigation.
`
`OEMs faced a predicament—if they refused to pay what Qualcomm wanted, they could
`
`not buy chips—from Qualcomm (or, for practical purposes, from a competitor). To maintain chip
`
`supply and stay in business, OEMs paid Qualcomm what Qualcomm wanted for SEP rights and
`
`agreed not to sue Qualcomm over its intellectual property portfolio. This policy was chip-supplier
`
`neutral, meaning Qualcomm did not officially mandate that OEMs buy chips from Qualcomm.
`
`11
`
`Northern District of California
`
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 3:17-md-02773-JSC Document 914 Filed 01/06/23 Page 12 of 37
`
`
`
`But Qualcomm then offered OEMs a large rebate for exclusive chip-buying arrangements.
`
`Plaintiffs argue this rebate was a coercive disloyalty penalty, not a “discount.” In other words,
`
`Plaintiffs allege that the combination of these practices inflated the “all-in” cost of modem chips
`
`for OEMs because OEMs paid for the modem chip itself, a FRAND royalty to access the SEP, and
`
`an added “surcharge” above that FRAND rate to ensure continued access to chips. (Id. ¶ 199.)
`
`Plaintiffs offer the following hypothetical to illustrate the harm to consumers and
`
`competitors. (Id. ¶ 74.) In this imagined scenario, a FRAND royalty for Qualcomm’s SEP license
`
`amounts to $5/chip. Qualcomm violates its FRAND obligations, and charges OEMs $15/chip for
`
`the SEP license. OEMs still have a choice to purchase chips from either Qualcomm or “Chip
`
`Competitor”—the policy is chip supplier neutral. Chip Competitor offers the OEM a $16/chip
`
`price. Qualcomm offers a $25/chip price and Qualcomm offers what amounts to $10/chip in
`
`“incentives” or “rebates” if the OEM buys 100% of its chips from Qualcomm. The OEM thus has
`
`two offers on the table:
`
`
`
`• Option 1: Buy from Chip Competitor for $31/chip “all in”
`o SEP Price: $15 to Qualcomm per SEP license per chip
`o Chip Price: $16 to Chip Competitor per chip
`
`
`
`• Option 2: Buy 100% of chips from Qualcomm for $30/chip “all in”
`o SEP Price: $15 to Qualcomm per SEP license per chip
`o Chip Price: $25 to Qualcomm per chip
`o Exclusivity Rebate: $10 from Qualcomm to OEM
`
`
`
`The rational OEM would, of course, buy from Qualcomm. If, however, Qualcomm abided by its
`
`FRAND commitments ($5/SEP license/chip), the following scenarios would be available:
`
`
`• Option 1: Buy from Chip Competitor for $21/chip “all in”
`o SEP Price: $5 to Qualcomm per SEP license per chip
`o Chip Price: $16 to Chip Competitor per chip
`
`• Option 2: Buy from Qualcomm for $30/chip “all in”
`o SEP Price: $5 to Qualcomm per SEP license per chip
`o Chip Price: $25 to Qualcomm per chip
`o Exclusivity Rebate: (Non-existent because Qualcomm does not have the
`
`12
`
`1
`
`2
`
`3
`
`4
`
`5
`
`6
`
`7
`
`8
`
`9
`
`10
`
`11
`
`12
`
`13
`
`14
`
`15
`
`16
`
`17
`
`18
`
`19
`
`20
`
`21
`
`22
`
`23
`
`24
`
`25
`
`26
`
`27
`
`28
`
`Northern District of California
`
`United States District Court
`
`

`

`Case 3:17-md-02773-JSC Document 914 Filed 01/06/23 Page 13 of 37
`
`
`
`
`
`supra-FRAND $10/SEP license to rebate)5
`
`In that scenario, the OEM would choose the $21/chip from Chip Competitor rather than the
`
`$30/chip to Qualcomm.
`
`Plaintiffs allege the first scenario occurred. As a result, (1) chip competitors could not
`
`break into the market because Qualcomm used the combination of SEP patent hold up, “no
`
`license, no chips,” and exclusive dealing to lock out competition, (2) OEMs overpaid because chip
`
`competitors could not compete, and (3) OEMs passed along those harms to individual consumers.
`
`D.
`
`Plaintiffs’ Alleged Injury and the Putative Class
`
`Plaintiffs Sarah Key, Andrew Westley, Terese Russell, and Carra Abernathy reside in
`
`California. (Id. ¶¶ 23–26.) Th

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket