throbber
Case 3:18-cv-07440-JCS Document 76 Filed 02/18/20 Page 1 of 23
`
`
`THEODORE J. BOUTROUS JR., SBN 132099
`tboutrous@gibsondunn.com
`DANIEL G. SWANSON, SBN 116556
`dswanson@gibsondunn.com
`GIBSON, DUNN & CRUTCHER LLP
`333 South Grand Avenue
`Los Angeles, CA 90071-3197
`Telephone: 213.229.7000
`Facsimile: 213.229.7520
`
`CYNTHIA E. RICHMAN, SBN 492089
`crichman@gibsondunn.com
`GIBSON, DUNN & CRUTCHER LLP
`1050 Connecticut Avenue, N.W.
`Washington, DC 11101
`Telephone: 202.955.8500
`Facsimile: 202.467.0539
`Attorneys for Uber Technologies, Inc, Rasier LLC,
`Rasier-CA LLC, Rasier-PA LLC, Rasier-DC LLC,
`Rasier-NY LLC, Uber-USA LLC
`UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
`NORTHERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA
`SAN FRANCISCO DIVISION
`
`SC Innovations, Inc.,
`
`Plaintiff,
`
`v.
`Uber Technologies, Inc; Rasier LLC; Rasier-
`CA LLC; Rasier-PA LLC; Rasier-DC LLC;
`Rasier-NY LLC; Uber-USA LLC,
`Defendants.
`
` CASE NO. 3:18-CV-07440-JCS
`DEFENDANTS’ MOTION TO DISMISS
`SECOND AMENDED COMPLAINT
`Hearing:
`Date:
`Time:
`Place:
`Judge:
`
`April 3, 2020
`9:30 a.m.
`Courtroom G, 450 Golden Gate
`Avenue, San Francisco, CA
`Honorable Joseph C. Spero
`
`
`
`
`
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`
`Gibson, Dunn &
`Crutcher LLP
`
`
`
`
`DEFENDANTS’ MOTION TO DISMISS – CASE NO. 3:18-CV-07440-JCS
`
`

`

`Case 3:18-cv-07440-JCS Document 76 Filed 02/18/20 Page 2 of 23
`
`
`TO ALL PARTIES AND THEIR ATTORNEYS OF RECORD:
`PLEASE TAKE NOTICE that on April 3, 2020, before the Honorable Joseph C. Spero, in
`Courtroom G of the United States District Court, Northern District of California, located at 450 Golden
`Gate Avenue, San Francisco, CA 94102, Defendants Uber Technologies, Inc; Rasier LLC; Rasier-CA
`LLC; Rasier-PA LLC; Rasier-DC LLC; Rasier-NY LLC; and Uber-USA LLC (“Defendants” or
`“Uber”) will and hereby do move this Court to dismiss, with prejudice, the claims brought by Plaintiff
`SC Innovations Inc. (“SCI”) pursuant to Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 12(b)(6).
`This Court dismissed all claims asserted in SCI’s First Amended Complaint (“FAC,” dkt. 60).
`Order Granting Mot. to Dismiss [First] Am. Compl. (“Order,” dkt. 71). This Court found that, as a
`matter of law, Plaintiff’s factual allegations did not support a conclusion that Uber violated the Sherman
`Act § 2. Id. Specifically, this Court found that SCI did not allege (1) market power or (2) a cognizable
`probability of recoupment, and gave SCI the opportunity to amend its complaint to cure these defects.
`Id. at 12-16. This Court dismissed SCI’s claim under California’s Unfair Practices Act (“UPA”) with
`prejudice. Id. at 18-21.
`SCI’s Second Amended Complaint (“SAC,” dkt. 73) offers no new allegations to correct the
`deficiencies that condemned its FAC. Defendants’ motion to dismiss is based on the grounds that the
`SAC fails to state any claim upon which relief can be granted because (1) the Sherman Act § 2 claims
`fail to plead the possession (or a dangerous probability) of monopoly power; (2) the predatory pricing
`claims under Section 2 fail to allege the requisite elements of predatory pricing (exclusion of
`competition, dangerous probability of recoupment); (3) the “tortious interference” claims under Section
`2 are conclusory and lack any factual support, plead no injury to competition, and are based on lawful
`and justified conduct; and (4) the applicable statutes of limitations bar SCI’s claims in whole or in part.
`SCI’s UPA claim should be stricken since the SAC repleads it after it was dismissed with prejudice.
`This motion is based on this Notice of Motion and Motion, the concurrently filed Memorandum
`of Points and Authorities, the pleadings and papers on file, and the argument received by the Court.
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`
`Gibson, Dunn &
`Crutcher LLP
`
`
`
`ii
`DEFENDANTS’ MOTION TO DISMISS – CASE NO. 3:18-CV-07440-JCS
`
`

`

`Case 3:18-cv-07440-JCS Document 76 Filed 02/18/20 Page 3 of 23
`
`
`
`THEODORE J. BOUTROUS JR.
`DANIEL G. SWANSON
`CYNTHIA E. RICHMAN
`GIBSON, DUNN & CRUTCHER LLP
`
`/s/ Daniel G. Swanson
`By:
`
`Attorneys for Uber Technologies, Inc, Rasier LLC,
`Rasier-CA LLC, Rasier-PA LLC, Rasier-DC LLC,
`Rasier-NY LLC, Uber-USA LLC
`
`
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`
`Gibson, Dunn &
`Crutcher LLP
`
`
`
`iii
`DEFENDANTS’ MOTION TO DISMISS – CASE NO. 3:18-CV-07440-JCS
`
`

`

`Case 3:18-cv-07440-JCS Document 76 Filed 02/18/20 Page 4 of 23
`
`TABLE OF CONTENTS
`
`Page
`INTRODUCTION .................................................................................................................... 1
`SCI’s REVISED ALLEGATIONS ........................................................................................... 1
`LEGAL STANDARD ............................................................................................................... 2
`SCI FAILS TO PLEAD A CLAIM UNDER SHERMAN ACT § 2 ........................................ 2
`A.
`SCI Fails To Plead Market Power ................................................................................. 3
`1.
`SCI’s New “Price Discrimination” Theory of Market Power Fails as a
`Matter of Law .................................................................................................... 4
`SCI Fails As a Matter of Law To Plead That Uber Has The Unilateral
`Power To Raise Overall Prices in a Two-Sided Transaction Market ............... 5
`SCI Again Relies On An Impermissible Oligopoly Theory ............................. 8
`3.
`SCI Fails to Plead a Cognizable Probability of Recoupment ..................................... 10
`B.
`SCI Fails to Plead an Antitrust Claim for Alleged Tortious Interference ................... 12
`C.
`SCI’s Unfair Practices Act Claim Should Be Stricken ............................................... 15
`D.
`CONCLUSION ....................................................................................................................... 15
`
`2.
`
`
`
`I.
`II.
`III.
`IV.
`
`V.
`
`
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`
`Gibson, Dunn &
`Crutcher LLP
`
`i
`DEFENDANTS’ MOTION TO DISMISS – CASE NO. 3:18-CV-07440-JCS
`
`

`

`Case 3:18-cv-07440-JCS Document 76 Filed 02/18/20 Page 5 of 23
`
`
`
`TABLE OF AUTHORITIES
`
`Cases
`
`Page(s)
`
`A.A. Poultry Farms, Inc. v. Rose Acre Farms, Inc.,
`881 F. 2d 1396 (7th Cir. 1989) ........................................................................................................12
`
`Am. Prof’l Testing Serv., Inc. v. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich Legal & Prof’l Publ’ns,
`Inc.,
`108 F.3d 1147 (9th Cir. 1997) ...................................................................................................13, 15
`
`Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly,
`550 U.S. 544 (2007) ..........................................................................................................................2
`
`Brooke Grp., Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp.,
`509 U.S. 209 (1993) ....................................................................................................................5, 13
`
`Copperweld Corp. v. Ind. Tube Corp.,
`467 U.S. 752 (1984) ........................................................................................................................13
`
`GMA Cover Corp. v. Saab Barracuda LLC,
`2012 WL 642739 (E.D. Mich. Feb. 8, 2012) ..................................................................................10
`
`Harrison Aire, Inc. v. Aerostar Int’l, Inc.,
`423 F.3d 374 (3d Cir. 2005) ..............................................................................................................3
`
`Hunt-Wesson Foods, Inc. v. Ragu Foods, Inc.,
`627 F.2d 919 (9th Cir. 1980) .............................................................................................................3
`
`Illinois Tool Works Inc. v. Independent Ink, Inc.,
`547 US 28 (2006) ..............................................................................................................................5
`
`Indiana Grocery, Inc. v. Super Valu Stores, Inc.,
`864 F.2d 1409 (7th Cir. 1989) ...............................................................................................8, 11, 12
`
`Kendall v. Visa U.S.A., Inc.,
`518 F.3d 1042 (9th Cir. 2008) .........................................................................................................14
`
`Kolon Indus. v. E.I. DuPont de Nemours & Co.,
`748 F.3d 160 (4th Cir. 2014) .............................................................................................................5
`
`Malden Transp. v. Uber Techs.,
`321 F. Supp. 3d 174 (D. Mass. 2018) .............................................................................................15
`
`Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp.,
`475 U.S. 574 (1986) ........................................................................................................................10
`
`Metro Mobile CTS, Inc. v. NewVector Communications, Inc.,
`892 F.2d 62 (9th Cir. 1989) ...........................................................................................................3, 4
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`
`Gibson, Dunn &
`Crutcher LLP
`
`ii
`DEFENDANTS’ MOTION TO DISMISS – CASE NO. 3:18-CV-07440-JCS
`
`

`

`Case 3:18-cv-07440-JCS Document 76 Filed 02/18/20 Page 6 of 23
`
`
`
`Mount Hamilton Partners LLC v. Groupon, Inc.,
`2014 WL 1047408 (N.D. Cal. March 14, 2014) ...............................................................................4
`
`Novell, Inc. v. Microsoft Corp.,
`731 F.3d 1064 (10th Cir. 2013) .......................................................................................................13
`
`Oahu Gas Serv., Inc. v. Pac. Res., Inc.,
`838 F.2d 360 (9th Cir. 1988) ...........................................................................................................15
`
`Ohio v. American Express Co.,
`138 S. Ct. 2274 (2018) ................................................................................................1, 2, 6, 7, 8, 10
`
`Phila. Taxi Ass’n, Inc. v. Uber Techs., Inc.,
`886 F.3d 332 (3d Cir. 2018) ......................................................................................................12, 15
`
`Rebel Oil Co., Inc. v. Atl. Richfield Co.,
`146 F.3d 1088 (9th Cir. 1998) .........................................................................................................12
`
`Rebel Oil Co., Inc. v. Atl. Richfield Co.,
`51 F.3d 1421 (9th Cir. 1995) ...........................................................................3, 4, 5, 8, 9, 10, 11, 12
`
`Smilecare Dental Group v. Delta Dental Plan of California, Inc.,
`88 F.3d 780 (9th Cir. 1996) ...............................................................................................................3
`
`Somers v. Apple, Inc.,
`729 F. 3d 953 (9th Cir. 2013) ............................................................................................................2
`
`TI Inv. Servs., LLC v. Microsoft Corp.,
`23 F. Supp. 3d 451 (D.N.J. 2014) ...................................................................................................10
`
`United States v. Grinnell Corp.,
`384 U.S. 563 (1966) ..........................................................................................................................3
`
`Vess v. Ciba-Geigy Corp. USA,
`317 F. 3d 1097 (9th Cir. 2003) ........................................................................................................13
`
`Other Authorities
`
`3 P. Areeda & D. Turner, Antitrust Law ¶ 7381 (1978) .......................................................................15
`
`Philip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Fundamentals of Antitrust Law §7.08[A] ...........................13
`
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`
`Gibson, Dunn &
`Crutcher LLP
`
`
`
`iii
`DEFENDANTS’ MOTION TO DISMISS – CASE NO. 3:18-CV-07440-JCS
`
`

`

`Case 3:18-cv-07440-JCS Document 76 Filed 02/18/20 Page 7 of 23
`
`
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`
`I.
`
`STATEMENT OF REQUESTED RELIEF
`Uber requests that the Court dismiss all of Plaintiff’s claims with prejudice pursuant to Federal
`Rule of Civil Procedure 12(b)(6).
`MEMORANDUM OF POINTS AND AUTHORITIES
`INTRODUCTION
`SCI has had three opportunities to state a claim under Section 2 of the Sherman Act. As with
`its first two attempts, the allegations in the Second Amended Complaint (“SAC,” dkt. 73) are deficient
`as a matter of law. SCI still admits—as it must—that Uber does not have the power to “reduc[e]
`overall market output.” SAC ¶ 91 (emphasis added). Such allegations, among others, cannot be
`squared with the Court’s Order, dismissing SCI’s claims. Order Granting Mot. to Dismiss [First] Am.
`Compl. (“Order,” dkt. 71) at 13-14. The SAC should be dismissed with prejudice.
`SCI’s REVISED ALLEGATIONS
`II.
`Uber will not repeat the allegations of the SAC with which the Court is already familiar. See
`Order at 2-6 (summarizing allegations in First Amended Complaint (“FAC,” dkt. 60)). Although SCI’s
`SAC adds a dozen paragraphs and deletes some prior terminology (like “duopoly strategy”), in effect
`it makes just three principal changes. First, SCI introduces a new theory alleging that Uber possesses
`the unilateral power to engage in certain kinds of “price discrimination.” SAC ¶¶ 12, 80, 84-85, 90-
`91, 103, 108, 112. According to SCI, passengers are subject to “discriminatory pricing tactics, such as
`surge pricing, and more recently, ‘dynamic pricing,’” id. ¶ 12, which SCI defines as “charging different
`customers different prices” based on the value they place on the service. Id. ¶ 85. SCI alleges that
`such “price discrimination” is the “primary way” that Uber will charge “supra-competitive” prices and
`realize “supra-competitive” profits. Id. ¶ 108.
`Second, SCI’s new pleading emphasizes the “two-sided” nature of ride-sharing applications,
`SAC ¶¶ 2, 11-12, 56, 70, 92, 110-11, and SCI repeatedly alleges that the relevant “ride-hailing market
`is a two-sided market.” Id. ¶¶ 2, 92, 111. “[T]wo-sided platforms often exhibit what economists call
`‘indirect network effects,’” which “exist where the value of the two-sided platform to one group of
`participants depends on how many members of a different group participate.” Ohio v. American
`Express Co., 138 S. Ct. 2274, 2280 (2018) (hereafter “Amex”). This is exactly what SCI’s new
`
`Gibson, Dunn &
`Crutcher LLP
`
`1
`DEFENDANTS’ MOTION TO DISMISS – CASE NO. 3:18-CV-07440-JCS
`
`

`

`Case 3:18-cv-07440-JCS Document 76 Filed 02/18/20 Page 8 of 23
`
`
`complaint pleads from the outset: “Both sides of the two-sided market are subject to substantial
`[indirect] network effects—the more riders Uber has, the more drivers it is able to attract, and the
`increased driver availability attracts even more riders.” SAC ¶ 2. These effects are particularly
`significant here given that the SAC confirms that ride-hailing apps are “transaction” platforms, which
`“facilitate a single, simultaneous transaction between participants.” Amex, 138 S. Ct. at 2286; see SAC
`¶ 32 (ride-hailing platforms “facilitate transactions” between drivers and riders). Such “two-sided
`transaction platforms exhibit more pronounced indirect network effects” than other two-sided
`platforms. Amex, 138 S. Ct. at 2286 (emphasis added). To account for such effects, “[i]n two-sided
`transaction markets, only one market should be defined” and that market must be analyzed “as a
`whole.” Id. at 2287 (internal quotation marks and citation omitted).
`Third, SCI adds various allegations throughout its amended pleading regarding the extent to
`which Lyft has allegedly been “weakened” by below-cost pricing and is vulnerable to the threat of
`continued losses. SAC ¶¶ 3, 12, 85, 90, 92, 110.
`As discussed below, whether viewed individually or together, these changes do not suffice to
`resurrect the claims under Section 2 of the Sherman Act that the Court previously dismissed.
`III. LEGAL STANDARD
`A complaint must be dismissed pursuant to Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b)(6) if it does not allege “enough
`facts to state a claim to relief that is plausible on its face.” Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544,
`547 (2007). “[A] plaintiff’s obligation to provide the ‘grounds’ of his ‘entitle[ment] to relief’ requires
`more than labels and conclusions, and a formulaic recitation of the elements of a cause of action will
`not do.” Id. at 555. “Factual allegations must be enough to raise a right to relief above the speculative
`level[.]” Id. “As the Supreme Court has emphasized, its insistence on specificity of facts is warranted
`before permitting a case to proceed into costly and protracted discovery in an antitrust case, especially
`where, as here, the potential expense of discovery is obviously great.” Somers v. Apple, Inc., 729 F.
`3d 953, 966 (9th Cir. 2013) (citing Twombly, 550 U.S. at 557-59).
`SCI FAILS TO PLEAD A CLAIM UNDER SHERMAN ACT § 2
`IV.
`SCI’s remaining claims arise under Section 2 of the Sherman Act. To plead a claim for
`monopolization under Section 2, a plaintiff must allege that: (1) the defendant possesses monopoly
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`
`Gibson, Dunn &
`Crutcher LLP
`
`
`
`2
`DEFENDANTS’ MOTION TO DISMISS – CASE NO. 3:18-CV-07440-JCS
`
`

`

`Case 3:18-cv-07440-JCS Document 76 Filed 02/18/20 Page 9 of 23
`
`
`power in the relevant market; (2) the defendant has willfully acquired or maintained that power; and
`(3) the defendant’s conduct has caused antitrust injury. Smilecare Dental Group v. Delta Dental Plan
`of California, Inc., 88 F.3d 780, 783 (9th Cir. 1996); see also United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S.
`563, 570-71 (1966). To plead a claim for attempted monopolization under Section 2, a plaintiff must
`allege: (1) specific intent to control prices or destroy competition; (2) predatory or anticompetitive
`conduct; (3) dangerous probability of success; and (4) causal antitrust injury. Smilecare Dental, 88
`F.3d at 783. As discussed below, the deficiencies the Court identified in the FAC have not been
`corrected in the SAC, leading the Section 2 claims to fail again for the same reasons. As a result, there
`is no need for the Court to address the additional flaws in SCI’s Section 2 claim based on alleged
`“tortious interference” but, at any rate, that claim is also defective for independent reasons.
`SCI Fails To Plead Market Power
`A.
`In order to state a claim for monopolization, SCI must allege monopoly power. Order at 12.
`“Monopoly power is defined as ‘the power to control prices or exclude competition,’” but “[m]ore
`precisely, it is ‘the power to charge a price higher than the competitive price without inducing so rapid
`and great an expansion of output from competing firms as to make the supracompetitive price
`untenable.’” Harrison Aire, Inc. v. Aerostar Int’l, Inc., 423 F.3d 374, 380 (3d Cir. 2005) (citations
`omitted). As this Court has previously held, SCI’s market share allegations do not alone suffice to
`plead that Uber possesses market power. Order at 12. “‘Blind reliance upon market share, divorced
`from commercial reality, [can] give a misleading picture of a firm’s actual ability to control prices or
`exclude competition.’” Metro Mobile CTS, Inc. v. NewVector Communications, Inc., 892 F.2d 62, 63
`(9th Cir. 1989) (quoting Hunt-Wesson Foods, Inc. v. Ragu Foods, Inc., 627 F.2d 919, 924 (9th Cir.
`1980)). Despite alleging that Uber holds ostensibly high market shares,1 SCI’s prior pleadings made
`it clear that Uber actually lacks the unilateral power to “raise market prices above competitive levels
`simply by reducing its own output.” Order at 13; see also Rebel Oil Co., Inc. v. Atl. Richfield Co., 51
`
`
` 1 SCI continues to exclude taxis from the relevant market definition. Given the Court’s ruling on
`this issue, Order at 10-11, Uber assumes for purposes of this motion (only) that taxi companies are
`not actual rivals or potential entrants in the alleged relevant market.
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`
`Gibson, Dunn &
`Crutcher LLP
`
`
`
`3
`DEFENDANTS’ MOTION TO DISMISS – CASE NO. 3:18-CV-07440-JCS
`
`

`

`Case 3:18-cv-07440-JCS Document 76 Filed 02/18/20 Page 10 of 23
`
`
`F.3d 1421, 1434 (9th Cir. 1995).2 SCI’s third complaint does not change this picture. While the SAC
`has added allegations about price discrimination, about the two-sided nature of the market and about
`Lyft’s “significantly weakened competition,” these new allegations fail to show that Uber possesses
`the requisite market power as a matter of law.3
`
`1.
`
`SCI’s New “Price Discrimination” Theory of Market Power Fails as a Matter of
`Law
`
`SCI’s amended complaint presents SCI’s latest theory of market power, asserting that Uber
`possesses the unilateral power to engage in certain kinds of “price discrimination.” SAC ¶¶ 12, 80, 84-
`85, 90-91, 103, 108, 112. For example, SCI pleads that Uber engages in price discrimination when it
`uses “surge” pricing and charges “temporarily higher prices in situations [of] high demand.” Id. ¶ 84.
`SCI also alleges that “[r]ecent reports indicate that Uber has moved to a more sophisticated form of
`price discrimination through a pricing model known as ‘dynamic pricing.’”4 Id. ¶ 85. SCI alleges that
`such “price discrimination” is the “primary way” that Uber will charge “supra-competitive” prices and
`realize “supra-competitive” profits. Id. ¶ 108. But allegations that a defendant has the unilateral ability
`to engage in price discrimination do not suffice to show the kind or degree of market power required
`for a claim under Section 2 of the Sherman Act as a matter of law.
`
`
` 2 This failing was fatal to both SCI’s monopolization and attempted monopolization claims. Rebel
`Oil, 51 F.3d at 1437-43 (dangerous probability of monopoly power lacking as a matter of law where
`no unilateral power to raise price to supracompetitive levels).
` 3 Further, SCI does not address the Court’s holding regarding the significance of CPUC regulation.
`As this Court noted: “If the CPUC were primarily concerned with shielding consumers from
`excessive utility pricing, its decision not to interfere with Uber setting low prices might be a rational
`approach to that goal: consumers at least arguably benefited from those prices, and if Uber
`attempted to use the dominant market position that it obtained as a result to set supracompetitive
`prices in the future, the CPUC could exercise its regulatory authority at that time to prevent Uber
`from doing so.” Order at 21 n.9. In Metro Mobile CTS, 892 F.2d at 63, the Ninth Circuit held that
`similar state regulation was a factor that further confirmed that a defendant with a 100% market
`share lacked monopoly power. “Even if [defendant] were bold enough to attempt to control prices
`… it was constrained from doing so by the [Arizona Corporation Commission].” Id.
` 4 “Dynamic pricing” is a “time-honored business strategy” practiced by those who have perishable
`“seats” to fill, such as restaurants, airlines, hotels, rental car operators, movie theaters and the like.
`See, e.g. Mount Hamilton Partners LLC v. Groupon, Inc., 2014 WL 1047408 at *2 (N.D. Cal.
`March 14, 2014). Such pricing is common throughout the economy.
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`
`Gibson, Dunn &
`Crutcher LLP
`
`
`
`4
`DEFENDANTS’ MOTION TO DISMISS – CASE NO. 3:18-CV-07440-JCS
`
`

`

`Case 3:18-cv-07440-JCS Document 76 Filed 02/18/20 Page 11 of 23
`
`
`
`To the extent that the “ability to price discriminate” may entail some degree of market power,
`such a “showing of [defendant’s] ‘market power’ is not itself sufficient to prove that [defendant]
`possesses ‘monopoly power.’” Kolon Indus. v. E.I. DuPont de Nemours & Co., 748 F.3d 160, 174 (4th
`Cir. 2014) (emphasis added). Even in cases under Section 1 of the Sherman Act, which requires a
`lesser showing of market power, price discrimination does not “give rise to a presumption of market
`power … standing alone” since “it is generally recognized that it also occurs in fully competitive
`markets.” Illinois Tool Works Inc. v. Independent Ink, Inc., 547 US 28, 45 (2006). Under Section 2,
`the Sherman Act provision at issue here, “a predator has sufficient market power when, by restricting
`its own output, it can restrict marketwide output and, hence, increase marketwide prices.” Rebel Oil,
`51 F.3d at 1434 (emphasis added). But SCI’s theory does not address the power to raise prices
`marketwide and to “sustain them for an extended period.” Id. Instead, SCI alleges that Uber can charge
`temporary “surge” prices or otherwise raise prices selectively for some riders at some times in some
`locations.5 Nor does SCI’s theory entail any power to restrict marketwide output since SCI concedes
`that Uber’s alleged price discrimination occurs “without reducing overall market output.” SAC ¶ 91
`(emphasis added). But truly “[s]upracompetitive pricing entails a restriction in output.” Brooke Grp.,
`Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 233 (1993) (emphasis added). SCI’s theory
`simply “does not prove … market power, at least not the degree of market power to raise the concerns
`of the Sherman Act.” Rebel Oil, 51 F.3d at 1442. This failing alone compels dismissal.
`
`2.
`
`SCI Fails As a Matter of Law To Plead That Uber Has The Unilateral Power To
`Raise Overall Prices in a Two-Sided Transaction Market
`
`SCI now emphatically embraces the definition of the relevant market as a two-sided transaction
`market, a market definition whose legal consequences are governed by the Supreme Court’s seminal
`Amex decision. This market definition, however, does not assist SCI in pleading market power for two
`reasons. First, even if SCI’s “price discrimination” theory had any legal merit in a one-sided market
`case—and as discussed above, it does not—it would fail to show market power in a two-sided
`transaction market as a matter of law. That is, SCI’s theory ignores one entire side of the market (i.e.,
`
`
` 5 Indeed, the factors that govern dynamic pricing—“ability to pay,” “price sensitivity” and demand-
`supply balance, SAC ¶ 85—can easily result in lower prices.
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`
`Gibson, Dunn &
`Crutcher LLP
`
`
`
`5
`DEFENDANTS’ MOTION TO DISMISS – CASE NO. 3:18-CV-07440-JCS
`
`

`

`Case 3:18-cv-07440-JCS Document 76 Filed 02/18/20 Page 12 of 23
`
`
`drivers) and disregards the indirect network effects that are the hallmark of a two-sided transaction
`platform. Second, the necessary implications of SCI’s two-sided transaction market definition validate
`Lyft’s ability to expand output to defeat any attempt by Uber to charge monopoly prices.
`As SCI’s complaint concedes, and as Amex teaches, two-sided transaction markets are
`characterized by indirect network effects.6 Amex, 138 S. Ct. at 2280. Thus, SCI’s amended complaint
`pleads that “[b]oth sides of the two-sided market are subject to substantial [indirect] network effects—
`the more riders Uber has, the more drivers it is able to attract, and the increased driver availability
`attracts even more riders.” SAC ¶ 2. The numerous added references to such network effects in SCI’s
`latest complaint suggest that SCI (mistakenly) believes that these effects ease rather than heighten
`SCI’s burden in pleading market power. But the reverse is true. As the Supreme Court has held,
`“[i]ndirect network effects … limit the platform’s ability to raise overall prices and impose a check on
`its market power.” Amex, 138 S. Ct. at 2281 n.1 (emphasis added).
`In view of such considerations, the Supreme Court has commanded that a two-sided transaction
`market must be analyzed “as a whole” because “[a]ny other analysis would lead to mistaken inferences
`of the kind that could chill the very conduct the antitrust laws are designed to protect,” including
`“legitimate price competition.” Amex, 138 S. Ct. at 2287 (citations and internal quotation marks
`omitted). But SCI’s approach to pleading market power is exactly the kind of partial analysis that the
`Supreme Court has warned against. Rather than address Uber’s ability to persistently raise overall
`prices in the market as a whole, SCI’s “price discrimination” theory improperly focuses only on Uber’s
`ability to raise prices to customers on one side (the passenger side) of a two-sided transaction market
`and, even then, only for some customers in some places at some times. In fact, SCI alleges that Uber
`has engaged in “discriminatory” surge pricing from the beginning while losing billions of dollars in the
`
` 6 “In other words, the value of the services that a two-sided platform provides increases as the number
`of participants on both sides of the platform increases. A credit card, for example, is more valuable
`to cardholders when more merchants accept it, and is more valuable to merchants when more
`cardholders use it. To ensure sufficient participation, two-sided platforms must be sensitive to the
`prices that they charge each side. Raising the price on side A risks losing participation on that side,
`which decreases the value of the platform to side B. If participants on side B leave due to this loss
`in value, then the platform has even less value to side A—risking a feedback loop of declining
`demand. Two-sided platforms therefore must take these indirect network effects into account before
`making a change in price on either side.” Amex, 138 S. Ct. at 2281 (citations omitted).
`
`1
`2
`3
`4
`5
`6
`7
`8
`9
`10
`11
`12
`13
`14
`15
`16
`17
`18
`19
`20
`21
`22
`23
`24
`25
`26
`27
`28
`
`Gibson, Dunn &
`Crutcher LLP
`
`
`
`6
`DEFENDANTS’ MOTION TO DISMISS – CASE NO. 3:18-CV-07440-JCS
`
`

`

`Case 3:18-cv-07440-JCS Document 76 Filed 02/18/20 Page 13 of 23
`
`
`market as a whole. Id. ¶ 9, 84.7 SCI’s approach is not legally valid in a case alleging a two-sided
`transaction market.
`As the Supreme Court explained in Amex, even charging uniformly higher prices to one side of
`the market (which SCI does not allege) is not in itself proof of “market power or anticompetitive
`pricing.” Amex, 138 S. Ct. at 2285-86. That is, “[e]vidence of a price increase on one side of a two-
`sided transaction platform cannot by itself demonstrate an anticompetitive exercise of market power.”
`Id. at 2287. And even when the overall price of transactions has increased in the market as a whole,
`such evidence “does not prove … the power to charge anticompetitive prices” where there is no
`corresponding showing of output restriction. Id. at 2288. “Market power is the ability to raise price
`profitably by restricting output.” Id. (original emphasis; internal quotation marks omitted). This of
`course accords with the Ninth Circuit’s holding in Rebel Oil. But SCI alleges no such power to restrict
`market output. As already noted, SCI makes the damning admission that Uber’s alleged price
`discrimination occurs “without reducing overall market output.” SAC ¶ 91 (emphasis added). Nor
`could SCI honestly allege otherwise given that it recently affirmed (in opposing dismissal of its prior
`complaint) that the market “has grown significantly … and likely will continue to grow.” Pl.’s Resp.
`to Defs.’ Mot. to Dismiss FAC at 11 (dkt. 67). SCI’s price discrimination theory thus fails to plead
`that Uber has the ability to restrict overall output in a two-sided transaction market.
`But this is not the only legal defect in SCI’s complaint injected by its own market definition.
`The existence of a two-sided transaction market also undermines SCI’s conclusory assertions that Lyft
`would be unable to expand output in response to monopoly prices. That is so because if Uber were to
`reduce output, it would lose the benefit of indirect network effects, see, e.g., SAC ¶¶ 73-75, while Lyft
`would gain those benefits by expanding output. Because of such network effects, “

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket