throbber
Case 8:14-cv-00111-PWG Document 686 Filed 12/01/17 Page 1 of 52
`
`IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
`FOR THE DISTRICT OF MARYLAND
`Southern Division
`
`
`
`INTELLECTUAL VENTURES I LLC,
`et al.,
`
`Plaintiffs/Counter-Defendants,
`
`
`v.
`
`CAPITAL ONE FINANCIAL CORP.,
`et al.,
`
`
`
`
`Defendants/Counterclaimants/
`Third-Party Plaintiffs,
`
`Case No.: PWG-14-111
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`*
`
`*
`
`*
`
`*
`
`*
`
`*
`
`*
`
`*
`
`*
`
`*
`
`*
`
`
`v.
`
`INTELLECTUAL VENTURES
`MANAGEMENT, LLC, et al.,
`
`
`
`
`
` *
`
`
`
`Third-Party Defendants/
`Joined Counter-Defendants.
`
`
`
`*
`
`*
`
`*
`
`*
`
`*
`
`*
`
`*
`
`*
`
`*
`
`*
`
`*
`
`* *
`
`MEMORANDUM OPINION
`
`The litigation history between the Intellectual Ventures companies (Plaintiffs, Counter-
`
`Defendants, Third-Party Defendants, and Joined Counter-Defendants to this action; collectively
`
`referred to as “IV”) and the Capital One companies (Defendants, Counterclaimants, and Third-
`
`Party Plaintiffs in this action; collectively referred to as “Capital One”) is protracted, beginning
`
`with a patent infringement action that Intellectual Ventures I, LLC and Intellectual Ventures II,
`
`LLC (together, “IV I and II”) filed in the Eastern District of Virginia on June 19, 2013. In that
`
`case, as well as in this patent infringement action that IV I and II filed on January 15, 2014,
`
`Capital One brought antitrust counterclaims. The Virginia court dismissed Capital One’s
`
`

`

`Case 8:14-cv-00111-PWG Document 686 Filed 12/01/17 Page 2 of 52
`
`antitrust claims for failure to state a claim, and IV now seeks summary judgment on very similar
`
`claims. ECF No. 656. Because Noerr–Pennington immunity and collateral estoppel both bar
`
`Capital One’s antitrust claims, I will grant IV’s motion.
`
`Procedural Background
`
`IV I and II filed suit in this Court, alleging that Capital One infringed five of their
`
`patents. Compl., ECF No. 1. IV I and II ultimately voluntarily withdrew one patent
`
`infringement claim and proceeded with the others. ECF Nos. 80, 81. The parties engaged in
`
`extensive discovery and agreed to referral to a Special Master highly experienced in patent law,
`
`jointly selected by the parties and appointed pursuant to Fed. R. Civ. P. 53. ECF Nos. 134, 136,
`
`143. He oversaw additional discovery, following which the parties extensively briefed the patent
`
`infringement claims. ECF Nos. 147, 147-1, 169, 169-1, 227, 246, 297, 300, 303. The Special
`
`Master issued two reports and recommendations, ECF Nos. 298 and 315, in which he ruled in
`
`favor of IV with respect to two of its patents, United States Patent Nos. 7,984,081 and 6,546,002
`
`(“the ’081 Patent” and “the ’002 Patent”), and in favor of Capital One on the claims related to
`
`United States Patent Nos. 6,314,409 and 6,715,084 (“the ’409 Patent” and “the ’084 Patent”).
`
`Both parties challenged the Special Master’s rulings adverse to them, and further briefing
`
`ensued. ECF Nos. 307, 311, 312, 313, 319, 324, 325, 330, 335, 336, 344.
`
`After reviewing the Special Master’s reports and recommendations and the parties’
`
`extensive briefs, I overruled the Special Master with respect to the ’081 Patent and the ’002
`
`Patent, finding that they were unenforceable. ECF Nos. 377, 378. I also ruled that collateral
`
`estoppel applied regarding the ’409 Patent and the ’084 Patent, barring IV from bringing claims
`
`against Capital One for infringement of those patents. ECF No. 382. The net effect of my ruling
`
`was that each of the patents that IV claimed Capital One had infringed was unenforceable, two
`
`2 
`
`

`

`Case 8:14-cv-00111-PWG Document 686 Filed 12/01/17 Page 3 of 52
`
`patents because I concluded that they were invalid pursuant to 35 U.S.C. § 101, and two patents
`
`because the United States District Court for the Southern District of New York in Intellectual
`
`Ventures v. JPMC, Case No. 13-3777-AKH, 2015 WL 1941331 (S.D.N.Y. Apr. 29, 2015),
`
`concluded that they were invalid, and issue preclusion barred me from reaching a different
`
`conclusion. On those grounds, I entered summary judgment in Capital One’s favor on those four
`
`remaining patent infringement claims. ECF Nos. 378, 382. And, finding no just reason for
`
`delay, I entered a final judgment in favor of Capital One on the patent infringement claims,
`
`making that order immediately appealable. ECF No. 387. The Federal Circuit affirmed my
`
`rulings, Intellectual Ventures I LLC v. Capital One Fin. Corp., 850 F.3d 1332 (Fed. Cir. 2017),
`
`thereby ending the patent infringement claims against Capital One.
`
`Meanwhile, Capital One had sought leave to file three antitrust counterclaims, claiming
`
`monopolization and attempted monopolization, in violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 15
`
`U.S.C. § 2, and unlawful asset acquisition, in violation of Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15
`
`U.S.C. § 18, as part of its Third Amended Answer, Defenses, and Counterclaims. ECF No. 106.
`
`IV I and II opposed the motion. ECF No. 118. I granted Capital One leave to file its
`
`counterclaims, ECF Nos. 194, 195, which it did, ECF No. 196; see also Fourth Amended
`
`Answer, Defenses, and Counterclaims, ECF Nos. 438 (redacted), 439 (sealed). It also filed a
`
`Third Party Complaint against additional Intellectual Ventures companies: Invention Investment
`
`Fund II, LLC; Intellectual Ventures Management, LLC; Invention Investment Fund I, L.P. ECF
`
`Nos. 228 (sealed), 230 (redacted). Capital One alleges that IV has tried, without success, to
`
`license to Capital One its extensive patent portfolio, which includes the patents that IV has sued
`
`Capital One, in this suit and the Virginia suit, for infringing. Capital One believes that IV’s
`
`repeated claims against it are actionable under antitrust law.
`
`3 
`
`

`

`Case 8:14-cv-00111-PWG Document 686 Filed 12/01/17 Page 4 of 52
`
`I denied IV’s motions to dismiss the counterclaims and Third Party Complaint, ECF Nos.
`
`225, 296, finding that Capital One had pled them sufficiently to proceed to discovery. ECF No.
`
`328. After another round of extensive (and expensive) discovery regarding liability on the
`
`antitrust counterclaims, I attended a tutorial involving the economic experts that the parties had
`
`identified. ECF No. 651. Also in attendance was the court technical advisor, Professor John M.
`
`de Figueiredo of Duke University Law and Business Schools, whose appointment the parties had
`
`confirmed on a status conference call, and who assisted the court in evaluating the economic
`
`evidence. ECF Nos. 606, 608.1 At the close of discovery, IV filed the pending Motion for
`
`Summary Judgment, which the parties fully briefed.2 In support of their positions, the parties
`
`jointly submitted a 13,344 page Joint Record, comprising 286 exhibits in sixteen, 3-inch binders.
`
`Having reviewed the parties’ memoranda and exhibits, I now rule.
`                                                            
`1 Unlike expert witnesses appointed under Rule 706, technical advisors are appointed under the
`court’s inherent authority, and they do not testify at trial (and are not deposed or subject to cross
`examination). Joe S. Cecil & Thomas E. Willging, Court-Appointed Experts in Reference Manual
`on Scientific Evidence 527, 531 (Fed. Judicial Ctr. 1994). Accordingly, Professor de Figueiredo
`did not provide his independent opinion on the issues, but instead helped me understand the
`parties’ experts’ methodology, any assumptions underlying the experts’ opinions, and how the
`methodology applies to the facts of this case. Thus, the purpose of the technical expert was to
`assist me in understanding the economic issues in this litigation and to enhance my ability to
`make an informed ruling on the pending motion. In this regard, Professor de Figueiredo’s
`assistance was invaluable.
`2 The parties fully briefed the motion. ECF Nos. 657 (sealed opening brief), 668 (redacted
`opening brief), 662 (redacted opposition), 664 (sealed opposition), 669 (sealed reply), 671
`(redacted reply). A hearing is not necessary. See Loc. R. 105.6.
`Also pending are motions to seal the opening brief and opposition. ECF Nos. 658, 665. I
`have considered the motions and other filings in this case, included redacted versions of the
`sealed documents, and in the interest of protecting confidential, proprietary, trade secret, and/or
`commercially sensitive information, I will grant the motions to seal.
`Intellectual Ventures also has filed objections to the Joint Record Exhibits, ECF No. 674
`(redacted), 675 (sealed), as well as a motion to seal its objections, ECF No. 676. Its motion to
`seal is granted for the same reasons that the summary judgment briefings are sealed. However,
`the objections are overruled. And, although I relied on the sealed briefings for this
`Memorandum Opinion, its contents do not justify sealing it, because the public’s interest in a
`public ruling outweighs the parties’ interest in sealing information related to this case.
`
`4 
`
`

`

`Case 8:14-cv-00111-PWG Document 686 Filed 12/01/17 Page 5 of 52
`
`Parties’ Arguments
`
`The essence of Capital One’s antitrust claim is that IV is a “patent troll,”3 and not just any
`
`patent troll, but a veritable Dovregubben.4 Capital One asserts that IV’s business practice is to
`
`acquire a vast portfolio of thousands of patents that purportedly deal with technology essential to
`
`the types of services offered by commercial banks (such as ATM transactions, mobile banking,
`
`on-line banking, and credit card transactions). It then employs an aggressive marketing scheme
`
`whereby it makes an “offer” for banks to license (Capital One really would prefer to say
`
`“extorts” banks to license) its entire portfolio for a period of years at a jaw-droppingly high
`
`price. But, Capital One insists, when the banks ask for details about the patents covered in the
`
`portfolio in order to determine whether their services infringe them, IV refuses to disclose
`
`sufficient information to enable them to make an intelligent decision about whether they should
`
`agree to the license. And, if the bank balks at licensing the entire portfolio at IV’s take-it-or-
`
`leave-it price, IV then threatens to file a patent infringement claim against the bank regarding
`
`only a few of the patents in the portfolio. Adding insult to injury, IV then makes it clear that
`
`should it lose the patent infringement case, it will simply file another (and if needed, another, and
`
`so on) regarding a different set of its patents, until the prospect of endless high-cost litigation
`
`forces the bank to capitulate and license the entire portfolio.5
`
`                                                            
`3 A “patent troll” is an individual or company “who acquires by purchase or application to the
`Patent and Trademark Office a patent that he uses not to protect an invention but to obtain a
`license fee from, or legal judgment against, an alleged infringer.” Carhart v. Carhart-Halaska
`Int’l, LLC, 788 F.3d 687, 691 (7th Cir. 2015). “Patent trolls are also known [as] ‘patent assertion
`entities’ (PAEs), [and] ‘non-practicing entities’ (NPEs).” In re Packard, 751 F.3d 1307, 1325
`(Fed. Cir. 2014).
`4 Dovregubben was the Troll King in Henrik Ibsen’s 1867 play Peer Gynt.
`5 Capital One is not the first to make these claims about IV’s business practices. E.g., Robin
`Feldman & Tom Ewing, The Giants Among Us, 2012 Stan. Tech. L. Rev. 1, 2–15 (2012).
`
`5 
`
`

`

`Case 8:14-cv-00111-PWG Document 686 Filed 12/01/17 Page 6 of 52
`
`Capital One characterizes IV’s business model as comprised of three components:
`
`accumulate a vast portfolio of patents purportedly relating to essential commercial banking
`
`services, conceal the details of those patents so that the banks cannot determine whether their
`
`products infringe any of IV’s patents, and serially litigate to force the banks to capitulate and
`
`license the portfolio at exorbitant cost. This conduct, Capital One insists, constitutes
`
`monopolization under § 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 2, attempted monopolization under
`
`§ 2 of the Sherman Act, and unlawful asset acquisition under § 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C.
`
`§ 18.
`
`Nonsense, IV indignantly responds. It counters Capital One’s charges by arguing that it
`
`legitimately purchased or otherwise acquired its large portfolio of patents that relate to multiple
`
`technology markets. It then offers to license its portfolio to banks (and other types of
`
`businesses), beginning its negotiation with an opening offer, and expecting the bank to
`
`counteroffer, thereby initiating a back-and-forth exchange that it hopes will result in a mutually-
`
`agreeable licensing fee. IV vehemently denies that it conceals the details of its individual patents
`
`or that Capital One could not determine what they relate to by reviewing publicly available
`
`information. As IV sees things, when Capital One declined to make a counter offer to its
`
`opening bid, it then selected a number of its patents and brought suit against Capital One, first in
`
`the Eastern District of Virginia, and then, when that suit was unsuccessful, in this Court, with
`
`respect to a different set of patents. Moreover, IV claims that Capital One is, in essence, an
`
`“efficient infringer”—an entity that engages in its business without care for whether it infringes
`
`on patents held by others, with the knowledge that a patent infringement case is expensive to
`
`bring, and many patent holders lack the funds to do so to protect their rights. As such, Capital
`
`6 
`
`

`

`Case 8:14-cv-00111-PWG Document 686 Filed 12/01/17 Page 7 of 52
`
`One can play the odds, infringing patents with near impunity until the rare patent holder with the
`
`resources to sue does so, and then negotiate a favorable license fee.
`
`IV points out that each of its patents is presumptively valid, and that it has an absolute
`
`right to file litigation to enforce them. And, in IV’s view, if enforcing its patents through
`
`litigation has any monopoly effect (which IV denies it does), it has immunity under the Noerr–
`
`Pennington doctrine.6 Moreover, IV argues that Capital One is barred by both claim and issue
`
`preclusion from asserting its antitrust counterclaims because it brought virtually the exact claims
`
`in the Eastern District of Virginia suit, lost, and elected not to appeal. Further, IV challenges
`
`Capital One’s definition of the relevant market for purposes of antitrust analysis, insisting that its
`
`portfolio consists of numerous distinct technology markets, not some monolithic “financial
`
`services portfolio” as claimed by Capital One.
`
`IV also asserts that Capital One’s antitrust theory is fundamentally flawed, because no
`
`liability can attach unless Capital One can prove that IV exercises monopoly power within a
`
`relevant market. “Monopoly power is the power to control prices or exclude competition.”
`
`United States v. E. I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 391 (1956); see Eastman Kodak
`
`Co. v. Image Tech. Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 481 (1992) (quoting E.I. du Pont); United States v.
`
`Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 571 (1966) (same). IV insists that it does neither, because the
`
`correct market definition would recognize that what IV owns is a series of patents that relate to
`
`multiple, distinct technology markets. And IV could exercise monopoly power only if Capital
`
`One can show that its patents include those affecting alternative substitute technologies that
`                                                            
`6 Under the Noerr–Pennington doctrine, “[t]hose who petition government for redress,”
`including by filing suit in court, “are generally immune from antitrust liability.” Prof’l Real
`Estate Inv’rs, Inc. v. Columbia Pictures Indus., Inc., 508 U.S. 49, 56, 57 (1993) (citing E. R.R.
`Presidents Conf. v. Noerr Motor Freight, Inc., 365 U.S. 127 (1961); United Mine Workers of
`Am. v. Pennington, 381 U.S. 657 (1965)).
`
`7 
`
`

`

`Case 8:14-cv-00111-PWG Document 686 Filed 12/01/17 Page 8 of 52
`
`Capital One otherwise could turn to in order to avoid having to license IV’s patents. Capital One
`
`has not made this showing, IV contends, entitling it to summary judgment.
`
`Antitrust Analysis and Economic Theory
`
`Underlying the legal issues in this case are two important but competing policies. On one
`
`hand, we value innovation that leads to new inventions that advance science and technology,
`
`protecting that creative effort by issuing patents. A patent, by its very nature, vests its owner
`
`with a type of legal monopoly, which it can enforce against anyone who infringes the patent.
`
`Enforcing a patent through litigation protects this monopoly, even though in other circumstances
`
`we view monopolies as harmful.
`
`The other important policy implicated by this case, of course, is the strong desire to
`
`ensure vigorous competition in the marketplace, so that consumers (whether businesses or
`
`individuals) can purchase at the lowest possible price. To promote the benefits of robust
`
`competition, antitrust law aims to prevent a company from having the ability to control the price
`
`of its product or exclude competitors to the extent that it can charge sustained supracompetitive
`
`prices (prices substantially above what a competitive price would be if consumers could simply
`
`buy a close substitute product from a competitor at lower cost).
`
`The exercise of monopoly power with regard to a single patent (or even a few patents)
`
`usually does not offend antitrust law. But it is another matter to acquire a vast portfolio of
`
`patents that are essential to technology employed by an entire industry and then to compel its
`
`licensing at take-it-or-leave-it prices because it is not economically feasible to determine if
`
`alternative technologies, not covered by the accumulation of patents, are available. This
`
`8 
`
`

`

`Case 8:14-cv-00111-PWG Document 686 Filed 12/01/17 Page 9 of 52
`
`acquisition and compelled licensing could amount to the ability to exercise monopoly power on
`
`an entirely different scale.
`
`In a very real sense, antitrust law is founded on economic theory about how efficient
`
`markets should operate. In an ideally competitive market where there are no barriers to entry or
`
`exit by competing businesses, the availability of the same product (or a close substitute) from
`
`many sources will tend to drive the price downwards to a point slightly above the cost to make
`
`the product—the so-called “competitive price.” Think of pizzerias. There are lots of them, and
`
`entry and exit from this business is relatively free and unrestricted. If one restaurant decides to
`
`charge too much for a slice of pizza, there are many others nearby where the consumer can buy
`
`at a lower cost. The ready supply of close substitutes keeps costs competitive—slightly above
`
`the cost of making the pizza.
`
`But, if circumstances are such that one pizzeria can exclude competition or control prices
`
`by charging more than a competitive price because consumers are unable to avoid paying it by
`
`turning to lower-priced alternatives, then it has the ability to exercise market power. And the
`
`power to control prices or exclude competitions is the essence of monopoly power. See Grinnell
`
`Corp., 384 U.S. at 571. Antitrust law is designed to prevent the acquisition and exercise of
`
`monopoly power. See id.; 15 U.S.C. § 2.
`
`Each of the above important competing policies is at play in this case. Capital One
`
`argues, through its highly credentialed and impressive economic expert, Professor Fiona Scott
`
`Morton of Yale University, that IV possesses monopoly power in connection with its large
`
`financial services patent portfolio, which touches on essential technologies that commercial
`
`banks have heavily invested in and cannot realistically design around to avoid the reach of IV’s
`
`9 
`
`

`

`Case 8:14-cv-00111-PWG Document 686 Filed 12/01/17 Page 10 of 52
`
`patents. Because of the size of this portfolio (between 7,725 and 35,000 patents, depending on
`
`whether Capital One or IV’s expert is correct),7 IV is able to charge supracompetitive prices to
`
`license the portfolio. And IV’s concealment of the details regarding the patents leaves Capital
`
`One unable (without incurring ruinous cost) to ferret out the particulars of each patent and assess
`
`whether it infringes any patents. Also at play is IV’s aggressive policy of threatening (and
`
`bringing) expensive serial patent infringement suits. IV’s aggregation of such a large portfolio,
`
`combined with its concealment and aggressive litigation strategies will, according to Capital
`
`One, eventually force it to capitulate and pay IV’s supracompetitive price to license the entire
`
`portfolio.
`
`As Professor Scott Morton sees it, antitrust analysis commonly used to determine
`
`whether a proposed merger will result in anticompetitive effects, simply does not work for the
`
`facts of this case. That is because merger analysis is ex ante, focusing on whether, if the merger
`
`is approved, the new entity will be able to charge a small but significant non-transitory increase
`
`in price (referred to as “SSNIP”)8 that it could maintain over time without competition from
`
`others making that price increase unsustainable. Put differently, SSNIP analysis is best done
`
`before the entity of interest has acquired monopoly power. Scott Morton reasons that this case
`
`requires ex post analysis because Capital One already had incurred significant costs to acquire
`
`the technology to compete with other commercial banks in essential services such as on-line
`
`                                                            
`7 According to Professor Scott Morton, IV has approximately 40,000 patents, 7,725 of which are
`financial services patents. Scott Morton Report ¶¶ 96 n.59, 170 n.136. Professor Gilbert asserts
`that “the portfolio that Intellectual Ventures initially offered to license to Capital One includes a
`much larger number of patents. Capital One’s complaint characterizes Intellectual Ventures’
`offer as covering 35,000 patents.” Gilbert Report ¶ 40 (citing Third-Party Compl. ¶ 40).
`8 See U.S. Dep’t of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm’n, Horizontal Merger Guidelines § 4.1.1 (Aug.
`19, 2010), available at https://www.justice.gov/atr/horizontal-merger-guidelines-08192010
`(discussing SSNIP).
`
`10 
`
`

`

`Case 8:14-cv-00111-PWG Document 686 Filed 12/01/17 Page 11 of 52
`
`banking, remote banking, and ATM and credit card transactions when IV began licensing its
`
`massive financial services patent portfolio. In other words, IV already had acquired monopoly
`
`power when it approached Capital One to license its patents. Because Capital One already had
`
`incurred substantial sunk costs in the technology in which it had invested, it was unable to design
`
`around IV’s enormous portfolio to adopt non-infringing technologies the way it could have done
`
`if it knew of the breadth and scope of IV’s patents before it incurred the cost of the technologies
`
`it adopted.
`
`Under her proposed ex post analysis, it is IV’s conduct after having acquired monopoly
`
`power that is critical to antitrust scrutiny. Through its trio of patent aggregation, concealment and
`
`litigation, IV has acquired insurmountable bargaining power enabling it to exercise “hold-up”
`
`power by demanding take-it-or-leave-it supracompetitive prices to license its financial services
`
`portfolio. And even though it has resisted doing so to date, eventually Capital One will be forced
`
`to capitulate to the threat of exorbitantly expensive patent litigation to purchase a license that it
`
`does not want, despite the fact that IV’s singular lack of success in prosecuting any of its patent
`
`suits against IV (or other banks) suggests that its massive portfolio is in truth composed of
`
`nothing more than an amalgamation of weak patents. And, but for IV’s practice of
`
`accumulation, concealment and litigation, it could never command a price to license its portfolio
`
`of weak patents at anything near the supracompetitive price it sought from Capital One.
`
`Scott Morton analogizes IV’s financial services patent portfolio to a “cluster market” that
`
`IV promotes as a single product (for which there are no close substitutes) at a supracompetitive
`
`price. And she asserts that IV exercises monopoly power, despite the fact that no bank (including
`
`Capital One) has agreed to purchase a license to the entire portfolio, and IV has yet to prevail in
`
`any of its patent suits against banks.
`
`11 
`
`

`

`Case 8:14-cv-00111-PWG Document 686 Filed 12/01/17 Page 12 of 52
`
`Pure humbug, counters IV, through its equally well-credentialed and impressive
`
`economic expert, Professor Richard Gilbert from the University of California, Berkley. He
`
`challenges Professor Scott Morton’s market definition, arguing that the proper definition is not a
`
`“cluster” of financial services patents constituting a single product, but rather a collection of
`
`patents that relate to multiple distinct technology markets. Professor Gilbert relies on the
`
`Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property issued jointly by the U.S.
`
`Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission (“Guidelines”). See U.S. Dep’t of
`
`Justice & Fed. Trade Comm’n, Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property
`
`(Jan. 12, 2017), available at https://www.justice.gov/atr/guidelines-and-policy-statements-
`
`0/2017-update-antitrust-guidelines-licensing-intellectual-property.
`
` The Guidelines
`
`state,
`
`relevantly, that “[a]lthough the intellectual property right confers the power to exclude with
`
`respect to the specific product, process, or work in question, there will often be sufficient actual
`
`or potential close substitutes for such product, process, or work to prevent the exercise of market
`
`power.” Id. § 2.2, at 4. The flaw in Capital One’s antitrust analysis, according to Professor
`
`Gilbert, is its failure to analyze the distinct technology markets for which IV does have patents to
`
`determine whether there are alternative close substitutes that Capital One could turn to in order
`
`to avoid having to license from IV.
`
`As Professor Gilbert sees it, IV’s patents touch on a large number of distinct technology
`
`markets, each of which must be analyzed using SSNIP analysis, which Professor Scott Morton
`
`failed to do. Thus, he strongly disagrees that IV’s patent portfolio can be analyzed as a cluster
`
`market at all. And, even more fundamentally, he challenges Professor Scott Morton’s
`
`conclusions, arguing that proper market definition and analysis requires looking at actual prices
`
`(competitive price, market price and monopoly price). Here, he insists, there are no prices at all
`
`12 
`
`

`

`Case 8:14-cv-00111-PWG Document 686 Filed 12/01/17 Page 13 of 52
`
`because IV’s licensing offer was only an opening bid in a negotiation, not a take-it-or-leave-it
`
`supracompetitive monopoly ultimatum. The negotiation did not progress to a point where a final
`
`demand was reached because Capital One refused to engage by making a counter-offer. Indeed,
`
`at least as of the time that discovery closed in this case, IV had not succeeded in selling a single
`
`license to its banking-related patents to Capital One or any other bank.
`
`As IV and Capital One agree, the essential first step in analyzing the antitrust claims in
`
`this case is to define the relevant market by product(s) and geography. See United States v.
`
`Marine Bancorporation, Inc., 418 U.S. 602, 618 (1974); Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370
`
`U.S. 294, 324 (1962); Buccaneer Energy (USA) Inc. v. Gunnison Energy Corp., 846 F.3d 1297,
`
`1319–20 (10th Cir. 2017). “[M]arket definition is a deeply fact-intensive inquiry . . . .” E.I.
`
`DuPont de Nemours & Co. v. Kolon Indus. Inc., 637 F.3d 435, 443 (4th Cir. 2011) (quoting Todd
`
`v. Exxon Corp., 275 F.3d 191, 199 (2d Cir. 2001)). In determining the relevant market, the Court
`
`must consider “the ‘commercial realities’ faced by consumers.” Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image
`
`Tech. Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 482 (1992). Where the facts are hotly disputed, as here,
`
`defining relevant market is “generally a question for the trier of fact.” ABA Section of Antitrust
`
`Law, Antitrust Law Developments 627–30 (ABA 8th ed. 2017), Ex. 127, Jt. Rec. 9557; see also
`
`Fineman v. Armstrong World Indus., Inc., 980 F.2d 171, 199 (3d Cir. 1992) (“[T]he
`
`determination of a relevant product market or submarket . . . is a highly factual one best allocated
`
`to the trier of fact.”). The burden of proof lies with the antitrust plaintiff to prove relevant
`
`market. Spectrum Sports, Inc. v. McQuillian 506 U.S. 447, 455–56 (1993); Berlyn Inc. v. The
`
`Gazette Newspapers, Inc., 73 F. App’x 576, 582 (4th Cir. 2003); Satellite Television &
`
`Associated Res., Inc. v. Cont’l Cablevision of Va., Inc., 714 F.2d 351, 355 (4th Cir. 1983). When
`
`the parties proffer competing economic experts on the proper definition of relevant market,
`
`13 
`
`

`

`Case 8:14-cv-00111-PWG Document 686 Filed 12/01/17 Page 14 of 52
`
`summary judgment is inappropriate as long as each expert’s views could be found by the trier of
`
`fact to be reasonable. Sprint Airlines, Inc. v. Nw. Airlines, Inc., 431 F.3d 917, 945 (6th Cir. 2006)
`
`(“‘[I]ntellectual disagreement’ among the parties’ experts creates material factual disputes on the
`
`relevant market . . . so as to preclude an award of summary judgment.” (quoting record));
`
`Thompson v. Metro. Multi-List, Inc., 934 F.2d 1566, 1573–74 (11th Cir. 1991) (“The parameters
`
`of a given market are questions of fact, and therefore summary judgment is inappropriate if there
`
`are material differences of fact.” (internal citations omitted)).
`
`IV does not dispute this authority, but contends that it is entitled to summary judgment
`
`despite the substantial disagreement between Professor Scott Morton and Professor Gilbert on
`
`the definition of relevant market (as well as other antitrust elements) because the methodology
`
`used by Professor Scott Morton is so far removed from commonly employed antitrust analysis
`
`that it must be rejected as unreasonable as a matter of law. It is true that Professor Gilbert’s
`
`analysis of relevant market is firmly grounded in commonly used antitrust analysis, as evidenced
`
`by its reliance on the Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission’s Antitrust
`
`Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property. But, in support of their alternative
`
`analysis, Capital One and Professor Scott Morton have cited authority for the application of
`
`cluster market analysis to the definition of a relevant antitrust market. See United States v. Phila.
`
`Nat’l Bank, 374 U.S. 321, 355–56 (1963) (citing Brown Shoe); United States v. Grinnell Corp.,
`
`384 U.S. 563, 572–73 (1966) (citing Brown Shoe); Brown Shoe, 370 U.S. at 324–25; and Fed.
`
`Trade Comm’n v. Staples, Inc., 190 F. Supp. 3d 100, 116–17 (D.D.C. 2016) (citing Brown Shoe);
`
`see also Ian Ayres, Rationalizing Antitrust Cluster Markets, 95 Yale L. J. 109 (1985). And,
`
`Professor Scott Morton has noted that the Department of Justice Horizontal Merger Guidelines
`
`that Professor Gilbert referenced do recognize that “[e]vidence of competitive effects can inform
`
`14 
`
`

`

`Case 8:14-cv-00111-PWG Document 686 Filed 12/01/17 Page 15 of 52
`
`market definition, just as market definition can be informative regarding competitive effects.”
`
`Horizontal Merger Guidelines § 4.
`
`With respect to cluster markets, Professor Ayres, one of the early scholars to study such
`
`markets in antitrust law, was critical of the courts’ failure to articulate “a sound justifying
`
`theory” of when cluster analysis is appropriate, opting instead for a series of “ad hoc” standards.
`
`He noted:
`
`The lack of a justifying theory apparent in Philadelphia National Bank and
`Grinnell has left lower courts virtually unconstrained to develop additional
`criteria for cluster definitions. Lower courts have based cluster definitions on the
`existence
`of
`trade
`associations;
`census
`classifications;
`functional
`complementarity; common technology, distribution or marketing; a unique
`product group; and other market characteristics. While courts have a plethora of
`standards from which to choose, they currently have no basis for distinguishing
`the good from the bad (and the ugly). In sum, while some cluster markets have
`been defined correctly, the lack of a sound justifying theory has led courts to
`adopt conflicting and ad hoc standards. In a world in which antitrust defendants
`are usually multiproduct firms, the problem of deciding when to clust

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket