throbber
Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 39-1 Filed 10/19/20 Page 1 of 56
`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 39-1 Filed 10/19/20 Page 1 of 56
`
`EXHIBIT 1
`
`EXHIBIT 1
`
`

`

`
`
`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 28 Filed 08/31/20 Page 1 of 55Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 39-1 Filed 10/19/20 Page 2 of 56
`
`UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
`SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF NEW YORK
`
`
`
`MARIAM DAVITASHVILI, ADAM
`BENSIMON, MIA SAPIENZA, PHILIP
`ELIADES, JONATHAN SWABY, JOHN
`BOISI, NATHAN OBEY, and MALIK
`DREWEY, individually and on behalf of all
`others similarly situated,
`
`
`Plaintiffs,
`
`
`v.
`
`GRUBHUB INC., UBER TECHNOLOGIES,
`INC., and POSTMATES INC.,
`
`
`Defendants.
`
`
`
`Civ. No. 1:20-cv-03000-LAK
`
`JURY TRIAL DEMANDED
`
`
`
`AMENDED CONSOLIDATED CLASS ACTION COMPLAINT
`
`Plaintiffs, Mariam Davitashvili, Adam Bensimon, Mia Sapienza, Philip Eliades, Jonathan
`
`Swaby, John Boisi, Nathan Obey, and Malik Drewey, individually and on behalf of all others
`
`similarly situated, bring this action against Grubhub Inc. (“Grubhub”), Uber Technologies, Inc.
`
`(“Uber”), and Postmates Inc. (“Postmates”) and allege as follows:
`
`I.
`
`INTRODUCTION
`
`1.
`
`Defendants have violated Section 1 of the Sherman Act and its state analogues by
`
`exploiting, without procompetitive justification, their dominant position in the market for delivery
`
`and takeout through internet-based platforms that aggregate the offerings of multiple restaurants.
`
`2.
`
`Over the past decade, as smart phones have become ubiquitous, the popularity of
`
`these platforms has skyrocketed. Because most restaurants face low profit margins, they require
`
`

`

`
`
`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 28 Filed 08/31/20 Page 2 of 55Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 39-1 Filed 10/19/20 Page 3 of 56
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`significant volume to cover their costs. To achieve such volume, restaurants must sell through
`
`Defendants’ platforms, which each have tens of millions of active users.
`
`3.
`
`Defendants use their market power to force any restaurant that sells goods on
`
`Defendants’ platforms to pay unreasonable commissions, typically equal to 30% of every order,
`
`each time a consumer orders from that restaurant through the platform. These commissions are so
`
`large that, when restaurants sell through Defendants’ platforms, they must increase their prices just
`
`to avoid losing money on each sale.
`
`4.
`
`In a freely competitive market, these restaurants could offset these increased costs
`
`by increasing prices for consumers who choose the convenience of Defendants’ platforms, while
`
`maintaining lower prices for consumers who order directly from the restaurants. That is, these
`
`restaurants would offer their customers different prices depending on whether they used
`
`Defendants’ platforms or placed orders directly through the restaurant.
`
`5.
`
`Insulating their platforms, however, each Defendant prevents the restaurants by
`
`contract from offering lower prices for sales outside its platform. For each Defendant, these
`
`restrictions apply to direct orders from the restaurants for takeout, delivery, or dine-in meals, even
`
`if those consumers do no business with Defendants. Grubhub and Uber apply these contractual
`
`restrictions most broadly by also preventing restaurants from charging lower prices for orders
`
`through similar platforms, such as Doordash.
`
`6.
`
`Defendants do this because if the restaurants were to offer consumers lower prices
`
`for sales outside each Defendant’s platform, then the restaurants’ sales on the platform would
`
`decrease, and Defendants’ supracompetitive profits would be threatened.
`
`7.
`
`The contractual restrictions that Defendants impose on restaurants thus prevent
`
`both restaurants and other platforms from competing on price with Defendants. As a result of
`
`
`
`2
`
`

`

`
`
`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 28 Filed 08/31/20 Page 3 of 55Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 39-1 Filed 10/19/20 Page 4 of 56
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Defendants’ conduct, any restaurant using any Defendant’s platform charges all of its customers
`
`supracompetitive prices.
`
`8.
`
`These agreements thereby cause substantial anticompetitive harm that, including
`
`with respect to the millions of consumers who are not even using Defendants’ platforms, lacks
`
`procompetitive justification. Indeed, although the courts in this country have not yet had occasion
`
`to do so, European regulators have repeatedly concluded that nearly identical contractual
`
`restrictions cause anticompetitive harm. In fact, bans on such provisions have resulted in lower
`
`prices for consumers.
`
`9.
`
`Accordingly, on behalf of a nationwide class of the customers of restaurants using
`
`these platforms, Plaintiffs seek to redress and enjoin Defendants’ unlawful conduct, occurring
`
`from April 13, 2016, to the present (the “Class Period”).
`
`II.
`
`PARTIES
`
`a. Plaintiffs
`
`10.
`
`Plaintiff Mariam Davitashvili is a resident and citizen of New York. Over the
`
`relevant period, she has ordered meals for takeout, delivery, and dine-in directly from restaurants
`
`that sell their goods through Defendants’ platforms.
`
`11.
`
`Plaintiff Adam Bensimon is a resident and citizen of New York. Over the relevant
`
`period, he has ordered meals for takeout, delivery, and dine-in directly from restaurants that sell
`
`their goods through Defendants’ platforms.
`
`12.
`
`Plaintiff Mia Sapienza is a resident and citizen of New York. Over the relevant
`
`period, she has ordered meals for takeout, delivery, and dine-in directly from restaurants that sell
`
`their goods through Defendants’ platforms.
`
`
`
`3
`
`

`

`
`
`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 28 Filed 08/31/20 Page 4 of 55Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 39-1 Filed 10/19/20 Page 5 of 56
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`13.
`
`Plaintiff Phil Eliades is a resident of New York, New York, and a citizen of New
`
`York. Over the relevant period, he has placed orders for takeout, delivery, and dine-in directly
`
`from restaurants that sell their goods through each Defendant’s platform, and indirectly from such
`
`restaurants through Doordash.
`
`14.
`
`Plaintiff Jonathan Swaby is a resident of New York, New York, and a citizen of
`
`New York. Over the relevant period, he has placed orders for takeout, delivery, and dine-in
`
`directly from restaurants that sell their goods through each Defendant’s platform, and indirectly
`
`from such restaurants through Doordash.
`
`15.
`
`Plaintiff John Boisi is a resident of Brooklyn, New York, and a citizen of New
`
`York. Over the relevant period, he has placed orders for takeout and dine-in directly from
`
`restaurants that sell their goods through Grubhub and Postmates, and indirectly from such
`
`restaurants through Caviar and Doordash.
`
`16.
`
`Plaintiff Nate Obey is a resident of Brooklyn, New York, and a citizen of New
`
`York. Over the relevant period, he has placed orders for takeout and dine-in directly from
`
`restaurants that sell their goods through Grubhub, and indirectly from such restaurants through
`
`Caviar.
`
`17.
`
`Plaintiff Malik Drewey is a resident of Queens, New York, and a citizen of New
`
`York. Over the relevant period, he has placed orders for takeout and dine-in directly from
`
`restaurants that sell their goods through each Defendant’s platform, but he has not used any of
`
`those platforms.
`
`b. Defendants
`
`18.
`
`Defendant Grubhub is a Delaware corporation with its principal place of business
`
`in Chicago, Illinois. Grubhub says it “connects more than 300,000 restaurants with hungry diners
`
`
`
`4
`
`

`

`
`
`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 28 Filed 08/31/20 Page 5 of 55Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 39-1 Filed 10/19/20 Page 6 of 56
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`in thousands of cities across the United States and is focused on transforming the takeout
`
`experience.” Grubhub’s 2019 revenues were $1.31 billion.
`
`19.
`
`Defendant Uber is a Delaware corporation with a principal place of business in San
`
`Francisco, California. Uber says its Uber Eats service “allows consumers to search for and
`
`discover local restaurants, order a meal, and either pick-up at the restaurant or have the meal
`
`delivered.” Uber’s 2019 revenues from this service were $2.5 billion.
`
`20.
`
`Defendant Postmates is a Delaware corporation with a principal place of business
`
`in San Francisco, California. Postmates says it is “transforming the way goods move around cities
`
`through [its] revolutionary Urban Logistics platform that connects customers with local couriers
`
`who can deliver anything from your favorite restaurant or retailer within minutes.” Postmates is
`
`not a public company; its reported valuation is approximately $2.4 billion.
`
`21.
`
`On July 6, 2020, Uber announced an agreement to acquire Postmates in a $2.65
`
`billion all-stock takeover.
`
`III.
`
`JURISDICTION AND VENUE
`
`22.
`
`This Court has subject matter jurisdiction under 28 U.S.C. § 1332(d)(2) because
`
`the matter in controversy exceeds the value of $5,000,000, exclusive of interests and costs, and is
`
`a class action in which any member of a class of plaintiffs is a citizen of a state different from any
`
`defendant. This Court also has subject matter jurisdiction under 28 U.S.C. §§ 1331 and 1337(a)
`
`and 15 U.S.C. § 15.
`
`23.
`
`Venue lies within this District under 15 U.S.C. § 22 and 28 U.S.C. § 1391 because
`
`Defendants resided, transacted business, were found or had agents in this District, and a substantial
`
`portion of the alleged activity affected interstate trade and commerce in this District.
`
`
`
`5
`
`

`

`
`
`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 28 Filed 08/31/20 Page 6 of 55Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 39-1 Filed 10/19/20 Page 7 of 56
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`24.
`
`This Court has personal jurisdiction over Defendants because this action arises out
`
`of Defendants’ conduct in this District.
`
`IV.
`
`FACTUAL ALLEGATIONS
`
`a. The Relevant Product Markets
`
`25.
`
`Coupled with the already increasing frequency with which restaurants had come to
`
`offer takeout and delivery service, the advent of the internet even further changed the food
`
`industry. Instead of calling a restaurant to place an order for takeout or delivery, customers could
`
`order on a restaurant’s website menu.
`
`26.
`
`Defendant Grubhub was one of the first companies to build and operate an online
`
`platform through which restaurant menus in a particular region are aggregated to allow consumers
`
`to view available pickup or delivery options all at once.
`
`27.
`
`These “Restaurant Platforms” enable consumers to search for participating
`
`restaurants in a particular locality and order food for takeout or delivery from those restaurants.
`
`Restaurant Platforms also deliver food for participating restaurants that do not want to provide
`
`delivery themselves.
`
`28.
`
`In aggregating the offerings of multiple restaurants in a single place, Restaurant
`
`Platforms provide a service distinct from a restaurant’s website or app (e.g., a Domino’s pizza
`
`app), which simply allow a consumer to place an order from a single restaurant.
`
`29.
`
`Restaurant Platforms thus compete with each other in the product market for
`
`takeout and delivery orders from Restaurant Platforms (the “Restaurant Platform Market”).
`
`30.
`
`For purposes of this action, two additional product markets are also relevant. First,
`
`in addition to offering meals for takeout and delivery through Restaurant Platforms, restaurants
`
`also sell meals directly to consumers for takeout and delivery (the “Direct Takeout and Delivery
`
`
`
`6
`
`

`

`
`
`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 28 Filed 08/31/20 Page 7 of 55Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 39-1 Filed 10/19/20 Page 8 of 56
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Market”). In the Direct Takeout and Delivery Market, a consumer may order directly from a
`
`restaurant for takeout or delivery by, for example, calling the restaurant’s phone number or by
`
`visiting the restaurant’s website. Second, consumers may also order meals to be eaten at a
`
`restaurant directly from that restaurant (the “Dine-In Market”). In the Dine-In Market, a consumer
`
`may order a meal from a restaurant and eat the meal at that restaurant, as opposed to taking that
`
`meal to eat elsewhere. These markets, in addition to the Restaurant Platform Market, are described
`
`in more detail below.
`
`b. The Restaurant Platform Market
`
`31.
`
`Although a number of firms participate in the Restaurant Platform Market, the
`
`market is dominated by just four firms: Doordash, Grubhub, Uber, and Postmates.
`
`32.
`
`According to data compiled by Vox, these firms control a remarkable 98% of the
`
`Restaurant Platform Market in the United States.
`
`33.
`
`Vox found that as of November 2019, Doordash’s national share of the market was
`
`37%, Grubhub’s share was 31%, Uber’s share was 20%, and Postmates’ share was 10%. This data
`
`underestimates Uber’s market share, because beginning in May 2019, some Uber Eats transactions
`
`became indistinguishable from Uber Rides transactions.
`
`34.
`
`These market shares vary across metropolitan areas. As The Atlantic has observed,
`
`Restaurant Platforms have “split their dominance regionally, like cable companies.” Grubhub, for
`
`example, controls 67% of the market in all of New York City, 4.5 times as much as its closest
`
`competitor in that market. Vox has summarized estimated shares in other markets:
`
`Local Market
`
`Grubhub Share
`
`Uber Share
`
`Postmates Share
`
`New York City
`
`SF Bay Area
`
`
`
`67%
`
`16%
`
`7
`
`14%
`
`13%
`
`4%
`
`8%
`
`

`

`
`
`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 28 Filed 08/31/20 Page 8 of 55Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 39-1 Filed 10/19/20 Page 9 of 56
`
`
`
`
`
`Miami
`
`Houston
`
`Phoenix
`
`Dallas-Fort Worth
`
`Washington, D.C.
`
`Boston
`
`Los Angeles
`
`Chicago
`
`Philadelphia
`
`Atlanta
`
`
`
`11%
`
`9%
`
`15%
`
`12%
`
`22%
`
`41%
`
`19%
`
`37%
`
`42%
`
`12%
`
`55%
`
`29%
`
`23%
`
`32%
`
`28%
`
`26%
`
`15%
`
`24%
`
`16%
`
`40%
`
`
`
`19%
`
`4%
`
`23%
`
`4%
`
`7%
`
`4%
`
`37%
`
`6%
`
`3%
`
`10%
`
`35.
`
`This result is the natural consequence not only of so-called indirect network effects,
`
`as explained below, but also of Defendants’ anticompetitive conduct.
`
`c. The Business of Restaurant Platforms
`
`36.
`
`Restaurant Platforms are two-sided platforms, acting as an intermediary to connect
`
`restaurants and consumers to the benefit of both.
`
`37.
`
`In its most recent 10-K, Grubhub describes its business as follows: “The Company
`
`connects more than 300,000 restaurants with hungry diners in thousands of cities across the United
`
`States and is focused on transforming the takeout experience.”
`
`38.
`
`In its most recent 10-K, Uber similarly describes its business as follows: “Our Eats
`
`offering allows consumers to search for and discover local restaurants, order a meal, and either
`
`pick-up at the restaurant or have the meal delivered.”
`
`
`
`8
`
`

`

`
`
`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 28 Filed 08/31/20 Page 9 of 55Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 39-1 Filed 10/19/20 Page 10 of 56
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`39.
`
`Postmates, on its website, likewise describes itself as follows: “Postmates is
`
`transforming the way goods move around cities through [its] revolutionary Urban Logistics
`
`platform that connects customers with local couriers who can deliver nearly anything from your
`
`favorite restaurant or retailer in minutes.”
`
`40.
`
`Grubhub, Uber, and Postmates, like other Restaurant Platforms, not only connect
`
`restaurants and consumers, but also derive revenue from both restaurants and consumers.
`
`41.
`
`Restaurant Commission. When a consumer orders from a restaurant through a
`
`Restaurant Platform, the platform typically charges the restaurant a commission (the “Restaurant
`
`Commission”). The Restaurant Commission is typically equal to a rate (the “Restaurant
`
`Commission Rate”) multiplied by the total price of the order.
`
`42.
`
`If the restaurant does not provide its own delivery, the total price is the listed price
`
`of the goods ordered (e.g., the total price of two burgers, one order of fries, and a soda). Those
`
`prices, which are typically chosen by the restaurant, are referred to as the Restaurant List Prices.
`
`If the restaurant provides its own delivery, the total price is the sum of the Restaurant List Prices
`
`for the goods ordered, plus the delivery fees the restaurant charges. Defendants typically charge a
`
`30% Restaurant Commission Rate to restaurants that do not provide their own delivery, and a
`
`lower Restaurant Commission Rate for restaurants that do provide their own delivery.
`
`43.
`
`Consumer Commission. A Restaurant Platform also charges consumers a service
`
`fee (the “Consumer Commission”). The Consumer Commission is typically equal to a commission
`
`rate (the “Consumer Commission Rate”) multiplied by the total listed price of the order. The
`
`Consumer Commission Rate is typically between 5% and 10%. In some cases, Restaurant
`
`Platforms charge no Consumer Commission Rates for orders from restaurants that provide their
`
`own deliveries and for takeout orders.
`
`
`
`9
`
`

`

`
`
`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 28 Filed 08/31/20 Page 10 of 55Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 39-1 Filed 10/19/20 Page 11 of 56
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`44.
`
`Consumer Delivery Fee. Restaurant Platforms also typically charge the consumer
`
`a delivery fee for orders from restaurants that do not provide their own delivery (the “Consumer
`
`Delivery Fee”). The Consumer Delivery Fee is typically about 5%.
`
`45.
`
`The following is an example of the fees that Restaurant Platforms charge:
`
`
`
`Restaurant List Price
`
`Restaurant’s delivery price
`
`Restaurant Commission Rate
`
`Restaurant Commission
`
`Consumer Commission Rate
`
`Consumer Commission
`
`Consumer Delivery Fee
`
`Total Charged to Consumer
`
`Total Revenue for Restaurant
`Platform
`
`
`Scenario A:
`Restaurant
`Platform provides
`delivery
`
`
`Scenario B:
`Restaurant
`provides delivery
`
`Scenario C:
`Takeout
`orders
`
`$50.00
`
`n/a
`
`30%
`
`$15.00
`
`5%
`
`$2.50
`
`$2.50
`
`$55.00
`
`$20.00
`
`$50.00
`
`$2.00
`
`20%
`
`$10.40
`
`0%
`
`$0.00
`
`$0.00
`
`$52.00
`
`$10.40
`
`$50.00
`
`n/a
`
`15%
`
`$7.50
`
`0%
`
`$0.00
`
`$0.00
`
`$50.00
`
`$7.50
`
`
`The Restaurant Platform Market is a separate product market from both the Direct
`
`46.
`
`Takeout and Delivery Market and the Dine-In Market. This is because a hypothetical Restaurant
`
`Platform monopolist could profitably increase prices, as measured by the fees charged to both
`
`restaurants and consumers, above competitive levels.
`
`47.
`
`Although consumers may order meals for takeout or delivery in the Restaurant
`
`Platform Market or the Direct Takeout and Delivery Market, direct orders from restaurants (i.e.,
`
`
`
`10
`
`

`

`
`
`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 28 Filed 08/31/20 Page 11 of 55Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 39-1 Filed 10/19/20 Page 12 of 56
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`orders in the Direct Takeout and Delivery Market) are not reasonably interchangeable with orders
`
`from Restaurant Platforms. This is the case for several reasons.
`
`48.
`
`First, Restaurant Platforms offer services that restaurants do not offer. Restaurant
`
`Platforms list different restaurants that offer takeout and delivery in a particular area and thus allow
`
`the user to choose a restaurant based on her preferences, including based on reviews provided by
`
`other users of the Restaurant Platform. In allowing consumers to rate and review restaurants that
`
`they have ordered from, Restaurant Platforms allow consumers to share their experiences. In
`
`contrast, restaurants in the Direct Takeout and Delivery Market simply offer consumers the ability
`
`to place an order after the consumer has already decided to order from that restaurant.
`
`49.
`
`For example, Grubhub has a five-star rating system that allows its users to rate an
`
`individual restaurant, leave a review, and inform others what they ordered from the restaurant:
`
`50.
`
`Second, Restaurant Platforms allow consumers to place orders through mobile apps
`
`and websites, without speaking with a person. Once a consumer has provided a Restaurant
`
`
`
`
`
`11
`
`

`

`
`
`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 28 Filed 08/31/20 Page 12 of 55Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 39-1 Filed 10/19/20 Page 13 of 56
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Platform with her payment information, then she can place future orders without providing that
`
`information again. Restaurants do not necessarily offer the same services; indeed, the vast
`
`majority of restaurants do not offer their own mobile apps and many do not offer online ordering.
`
`51.
`
`Third, as discussed in more detail below, Restaurant Platforms are “sticky,”
`
`meaning that consumers who become familiar with platforms are unlikely to switch to any other
`
`service, whether that other service is a competing Restaurant Platform or a restaurant website or
`
`mobile app. This means that a hypothetical Restaurant Platform monopolist could raise prices to
`
`a degree that it otherwise could not without seeing decreased profits.
`
`52.
`
`Fourth, although different consumers use Restaurant Platforms, they are especially
`
`popular among young professionals in major cities. This is a distinct group of consumers with
`
`distinct sensitivities to price changes and distinct preferences.
`
`53.
`
`These distinctions demonstrate that, if a hypothetical Restaurant Platform
`
`monopolist increased prices to 5% above competitive levels, not enough consumers would switch
`
`away from that platform to make that price increase unprofitable. As further support for this
`
`analysis, commentators and politicians have identified the Restaurant Platform Market as a distinct
`
`market, characterizing it as an oligopoly and calling for antitrust scrutiny of potential mergers in
`
`that market.
`
`54.
`
`Although (for purposes of antitrust law) the Restaurant Platform Market is distinct
`
`from the Direct Takeout and Delivery Market and the Dine-In Market, there is some cross-
`
`elasticity between the Restaurant Platform Market and those markets. If a hypothetical Restaurant
`
`Platform monopolist increased prices, some consumers would switch to ordering in the Direct
`
`Takeout and Delivery Market or the Dine-In Market. For example, it would not necessarily be
`
`profitable for a hypothetical Restaurant Platform monopolist to increase prices to more than 5%
`
`
`
`12
`
`

`

`
`
`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 28 Filed 08/31/20 Page 13 of 55Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 39-1 Filed 10/19/20 Page 14 of 56
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`above competitive levels. Put differently, a hypothetical Restaurant Platform monopolist that is
`
`already charging supracompetitive prices to restaurants and consumers may be unable, absent
`
`some other restrictive mechanism, to profitably increase those prices further.
`
`d. Defendants Contractually Restrict Restaurant Prices
`
`Defendants have leveraged their position in the relevant markets to force restaurants
`
`55.
`
`to enter into agreements that include clauses requiring uniform prices for restaurants’ menu items
`
`(the “No Price Competition Clause” or “NPCC”).
`
`56.
`
`In general, the NPCCs prohibit a supplier that sells through that platform from
`
`charging lower prices when that supplier sells through other channels. NPCCs may be broadly
`
`categorized as “narrow” or “wide.” In a “narrow NPCC,” the platform prohibits the supplier from
`
`selling its goods at a lower price when the supplier sells to consumers directly, as opposed to
`
`through the platform or some other non-direct channel. In a “wide NPCC,” the platform prohibits
`
`the supplier from selling its goods at a lower price when the supplier sells through any channel
`
`other than through the platform.
`
`57.
`
`Postmates imposes narrow NPCCs on restaurants that sell through Postmates.
`
`Postmates’s NPCC states: “Pricing shall be consistent with Merchant’s in-store pricing.” That is,
`
`“Postmates insists on price parity between in-store and online menus.”
`
`58.
`
`As a result, any restaurant that sells goods through Postmates is contractually
`
`prohibited from selling those goods at a lower price to consumers who purchase directly from that
`
`restaurant, regardless of whether the meal is for takeout, delivery, or dine-in, and regardless of
`
`whether that meal was ordered online, by phone, or in person. The restaurant may, however,
`
`charge a lower price when it sells its goods through a competing platform, such as Doordash.
`
`
`
`13
`
`

`

`
`
`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 28 Filed 08/31/20 Page 14 of 55Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 39-1 Filed 10/19/20 Page 15 of 56
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`59.
`
`Grubhub and Uber both impose wide NPCCs. Like Postmates’s NPCC, these
`
`provisions prohibit restaurants from selling at lower prices directly to consumers (regardless of
`
`whether the meal is for takeout, delivery, or dine-in, and regardless of whether that meal is ordered
`
`online, on the phone, or in person). But unlike Postmates’s NPCC, Grubhub’s and Uber’s wide
`
`NPCCs also prohibit restaurants from selling at lower prices to consumers through any competing
`
`Restaurant Platform. For a restaurant that sells through Grubhub or Uber, the restaurant’s
`
`Restaurant List Price on those platforms is the lowest price the restaurant is permitted to charge in
`
`selling its goods.
`
`60.
`
`Grubhub’s NPCC states: “The item pricing must be at least as favorable to the
`
`consumer as that which is available for Restaurant’s standard menu or offered to any 3rd party
`
`service.” Consistent with this provision, Grubhub boasts (in its 2019 10-K) that it offers “menu
`
`price parity with any other online ordering option.”
`
`61.
`
`Uber’s NPCC states: “Merchant may not make any Item available to Customers
`
`through the Eats App at a price that is higher than the price that Merchant charges in-store for
`
`similar Items. Merchant agrees that you will not make an Item available under this Agreement at
`
`a price higher than the amount Merchant is charging for similar Items through any comparable
`
`platform for food delivery services.”
`
`62.
`
`The Restaurant Platform industry as a whole demonstrates that Defendants’ NPCCs
`
`are not a necessary element of their business. Doordash, for example, does not impose these
`
`restrictions on restaurants that sell through its platform. Public reporting on Doordash highlights
`
`this distinction:
`
`For a very long time GrubHub forced stores to sell at the exact same
`menu price that they offered in store – exactly what you’re
`mentioning. But then DoorDash came out and said, “Hey
`restaurant, you do whatever you want for your pricing, if you want
`
`
`
`14
`
`

`

`
`
`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 28 Filed 08/31/20 Page 15 of 55Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 39-1 Filed 10/19/20 Page 16 of 56
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`to sell it on DoorDash at 10%, 15% higher, so forth.” So, lot[s] of
`restaurant clients really liked DoorDash as they could increase their
`prices to recover commission costs.
`
`Another publication characterized this fact as a key “differentiator” for Doordash, explaining that
`
`Doordash’s lack of NPCC was “a big win for restaurants” because it allows them to “increase
`
`prices on that platform to offset the delivery app’s commission fees, without increasing the in-
`
`house restaurant list price.”
`
`63.
`
`A 2016 Bloomberg article similarly reported: “An explanation for DoorDash’s
`
`price discrepancies can be found in a support document within the help section of the company’s
`
`website. It says partner restaurants may choose to charge customers more to make up for
`
`commissions paid to the delivery company.”
`
`64.
`
`Defendants’ NPCCs have forced consumers who purchase from restaurants directly
`
`or from other Restaurant Platforms to pay supracompetitive prices; have enabled Defendants to
`
`continue offering subpar technology and service; and have caused Restaurant Commission Rates
`
`to increase to such a degree that restaurants have been forced out of business. Defendants’ NPCCs
`
`are anticompetitive and do not have any procompetitive justification.
`
`e. Competition in the Restaurant Platform Market
`
`65.
`
`Restaurant Platforms compete with each other for both delivery and takeout orders.
`
`For an order to occur, a Restaurant Platform needs to match a consumer and a restaurant. As a
`
`result, in competing for orders, Restaurant Platforms compete with each other for both consumers
`
`and restaurants.
`
`66.
`
`Restaurant Platforms exhibit indirect network effects, in that the value that they
`
`offer to one side of the platform is a function of the extent of the use of the other side of the
`
`platform. A Restaurant Platform that more consumers use is more valuable to restaurants, because
`
`
`
`15
`
`

`

`
`
`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 28 Filed 08/31/20 Page 16 of 55Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 39-1 Filed 10/19/20 Page 17 of 56
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`the platform connects those restaurants with more consumers. Conversely, a Restaurant Platform
`
`that more restaurants use is more valuable to consumers, because that platform connects those
`
`consumers to more restaurants.
`
`67.
`
`These indirect network effects thus create a positive feedback loop for a market-
`
`leading Restaurant Platform. A Restaurant Platform that is popular with consumers is more
`
`attractive to restaurants and will therefore succeed in attracting more restaurants to the platform.
`
`Once more restaurants agree to use the platform, the platform becomes even more attractive to
`
`new consumers, who will also use that platform.
`
`68.
`
`In producing significant benefits to a market-leading Restaurant Platform, however,
`
`this positive feedback loop imposes significant barriers for smaller firms and new entrants. A
`
`small or new entrant cannot reasonably compete with larger Restaurant Platforms unless it can
`
`offer consumers a sufficient number of restaurants from which to choose. Conversely, the small
`
`or new entrant cannot realistically attract restaurants unless it can provide those restaurants with
`
`access to a sufficient number of consumers. Indirect network effects thus simultaneously make it
`
`easier for a market-leading firm to maintain its dominance and more difficult for a new entrant or
`
`smaller firm to establish a foothold.
`
`69.
`
`Even Amazon, for example, was unable successfully to break into the Restaurant
`
`Platform Market. As the New York Times explained: “Since it started in Seattle in 2015, Amazon
`
`Restaurants has struggled to gain a foothold in the restaurant delivery market,” where “nearly 80
`
`percent” of the market is controlled by “UberEats, Grubhub and DoorDash.” Accordingly, in June
`
`2019, Amazon Restaurants shut down.
`
`70.
`
`Indirect network effects alone, however, do not necessarily preclude new entrants
`
`or smaller firms from taking market share away from a market-leading firm. For example, one
`
`
`
`16
`
`

`

`
`
`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 28 Filed 08/31/20 Page 17 of 55Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 39-1 Filed 10/19/20 Page 18 of 56
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`journalist explained that Doordash was able to take market share away from Grubhub by
`
`expanding the services that it offered.
`
`Grubhub’s original model was a marketplace for consumers to order
`food from independent restaurants that already had their own
`delivery fleets. Though this was a game-changer for consumers, it
`constrained supply to only listing restaurants that could perform
`their own deliveries. This was a mistake.
`
`Postmates and DoorDash were the first to realize that if they could
`provide the broader group of restaurants that did not do delivery with
`the ability to do deliveries, they could dramatically increase the
`number of restaurants that could exist in the marketplace, thereby
`leapfrogging Grubhub’s selection (and liquidity).
`
`Once they realized this Achilles heel, Postmates and DoorDash
`raced to exploit the vulnerability with a growth-at-all costs
`mentality. Grubhub was caught backfooted. Grubhub thought that
`they had saturated the market, but they had only saturated a
`subsection of the market—independent restaurants that made their
`own deliveries. Meanwhile, DoorDash, Postmates, Uber Eats, and
`all other food delivery startups were racing to capitalize on the
`newer, bigger definition of the category.
`
`In addition to increasing the size of the market, Restaurant Platforms have also
`
`
`71.
`
`sought to gain and protect their market shares in a number of other ways.
`
`72.
`
`On the restaurant side, for example, Restaurant Platforms have sought to prevent
`
`competitors from signing up additional restaurants by entering into exclusive agreements with
`
`those restaurants. For example, Grubhub has an exclusive deal with Yum Brands (KFC and Taco
`
`Bell), Doordash has an exclusive deal with Chili’s and the Cheesecake Factory, and Uber used to
`
`have an exclusive deal with McDonald’s.
`
`73.
`
`On the consumer side, Restaurant Platforms

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket