throbber
Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 42 Filed 01/19/21 Page 1 of 15
`
`
`
`UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
`SOUTHERN DISTRICT OF NEW YORK
`
`
`
`MARIAM DAVITASHVILI, et al.,
`
`
`Plaintiffs,
`
`
`
`v.
`
`
`GRUBHUB INC., et al.,
`
`
`Defendants.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Case No. 1:20-cv-03000 (LAK)
`
`ECF Case
`
`Electronically filed
`
`REPLY MEMORANDUM OF LAW
`IN SUPPORT OF DEFENDANTS’ JOINT MOTION TO
`DISMISS PLAINTIFFS’ AMENDED CONSOLIDATED CLASS ACTION COMPLAINT
`
`
`
`
`
`

`

`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 42 Filed 01/19/21 Page 2 of 15
`
`
`
`TABLE OF CONTENTS
`
`TABLE OF AUTHORITIES .......................................................................................................... ii
`
`I.
`
`PLAINTIFFS FAIL TO PLAUSIBLY ALLEGE COGNIZABLE
`ANTICOMPETITIVE EFFECTS IN THE “DIRECT” MARKETS (COUNT I). ..............2
`
`A.
`
`B.
`
`As a Matter of Law, Alleged Harm in the “Direct” Markets Is Insufficient
`Without Harm to Competition Among Meal-Ordering Platforms. ..........................2
`
`Plaintiffs Fail to Directly or Indirectly Allege Anticompetitive Effects in
`the “Direct” Markets. ...............................................................................................3
`
`II.
`
`PLAINTIFFS FAIL TO PLAUSIBLY ALLEGE ANTICOMPETITIVE
`EFFECTS IN THE PURPORTED PLATFORM MARKET (COUNT II). ........................4
`
`A.
`
`B.
`
`Plaintiffs Fail to Allege That the Inter-Platform NDPs Cause Actual
`Anticompetitive Effects in the Purported Platform Market. ....................................4
`
`Plaintiffs Fail to Allege Durable Market Power or Other Indirect Indicia of
`Anticompetitive Effects in the Purported Platform Market. ....................................6
`
`III.
`
`PLAINTIFFS FAIL TO ALLEGE A PLAUSIBLE RELEVANT MARKET
`(COUNTS I AND II). ..........................................................................................................7
`
`A.
`
`B.
`
`Plaintiffs Fail to Allege a Plausible Product Market. ..............................................7
`
`Plaintiffs Fail to Allege a Plausible National Platform Market. ..............................9
`
`IV.
`
`PLAINTIFFS’ DERIVATIVE STATE LAW CLAIMS SHOULD BE
`DISMISSED (COUNTS III AND IV). ..............................................................................10
`
`
`CONCLUSION ............................................................................................................................. 10
`
`
`
`
`
`i
`
`
`

`

`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 42 Filed 01/19/21 Page 3 of 15
`
`
`
`
`
`TABLE OF AUTHORITIES
`
`CASES
`
`Page(s)
`
`In re Aluminum Warehousing Antitrust Litigation,
`833 F.3d 151 (2d Cir. 2016).............................................................................................2, 3
`
`Bookhouse of Stuyvesant Plaza, Inc. v. Amazon.com, Inc.,
`985 F. Supp. 2d 612 (S.D.N.Y. 2013)..................................................................................8
`
`Commercial Data Servers, Inc. v. International Business Machines Corp.,
`262 F. Supp. 2d 50 (S.D.N.Y. 2003)....................................................................................7
`
`Electronics Communications Corp. v. Toshiba America Consumer Products, Inc.,
`129 F.3d 240 (2d Cir. 1997).................................................................................................9
`
`Heerwagen v. Clear Channel Communications,
`435 F.3d 219 (2d Cir. 2006)...........................................................................................9, 10
`
`In re Keurig Green Mountain Single-Serve Coffee Antitrust Litigation,
`383 F. Supp. 3d 187 (S.D.N.Y. 2019)..................................................................................8
`
`Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc.,
`551 U.S. 877 (2007) .............................................................................................................4
`
`Mathias v. Daily News, L.P.,
`152 F. Supp. 2d 465 (S.D.N.Y. 2001)..................................................................................8
`
`Meyer v. Kalanick,
`174 F. Supp. 3d 817 (S.D.N.Y. 2016)..................................................................................8
`
`New York v. Deutsche Telekom AG,
`439 F. Supp. 3d 179 (S.D.N.Y. 2020)................................................................................10
`
`Ohio v. American Express Co.,
`138 S. Ct. 2274 (2018) .....................................................................................................6, 9
`
`People v. Tempur-Pedic International, Inc.,
`944 N.Y.S.2d 518 (1st Dep’t 2012) ...................................................................................10
`
`Prime International Trading, Ltd. v. BP PLC,
`784 F. App’x 4 (2d Cir. 2019) .............................................................................................3
`
`R.J. Reynolds Tobacco Co. v. Cigarettes Cheaper!,
`462 F.3d 690 (7th Cir. 2006) ...............................................................................................7
`
`ii
`
`
`

`

`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 42 Filed 01/19/21 Page 4 of 15
`
`
`
`Sentry Data Systems, Inc. v. CVS Health,
`379 F. Supp. 3d 1320 (S.D. Fla. 2019) ..............................................................................10
`
`Spinelli v. NFL,
`903 F.3d 185 (2d Cir. 2018).................................................................................................3
`
`Tops Markets, Inc. v. Quality Markets, Inc.,
`142 F.3d 90 (2d Cir. 1998)...................................................................................................7
`
`Toys "R" Us, Inc. v. FTC,
`221 F.3d 928 (7th Cir. 2000) ...............................................................................................7
`
`TSI Products, Inc. v. Armor All/STP Products Co.,
`No. 3:18-cv-1682 (MPS), 2019 WL 4600310 (D. Conn. Sept. 23, 2019) ...........................8
`
`United States v. Visa U.S.A., Inc.,
`344 F.3d 229 (2d Cir. 2003).................................................................................................7
`
`WorldHomeCenter.com, Inc. v. PLC Lighting, Inc.,
`851 F. Supp. 2d 494 (S.D.N.Y. 2011)................................................................................10
`
`Wright v. Ernst & Young LLP,
`152 F.3d 169 (2d Cir. 1998)...............................................................................................10
`
`In re Zinc Antitrust Litigation,
`155 F. Supp. 3d 337 (S.D.N.Y. 2016)..................................................................................3
`
`OTHER AUTHORITIES
`
`Rani Molla, Grubhub sale rumors highlight the state of the struggling food-delivery
`industry, Vox (Jan. 9, 2020),
`https://www.vox.com/recode/2020/1/9/21058674/grubhub-sale-food-delivery-
`struggling-industry ...............................................................................................................6
`
`
`
`iii
`
`
`

`

`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 42 Filed 01/19/21 Page 5 of 15
`
`
`
`Plaintiffs’ opposition brief does not salvage their claims. Plaintiffs fail to overcome that
`
`they are challenging contractual provisions that prevent restaurants from charging higher menu
`
`prices to consumers on Defendants’ platforms. Plaintiffs also ignore their factual allegations
`
`suggesting Defendants compete in a growing and competitive marketplace for food delivery
`
`services where neither consumers nor restaurants are forced to use any Defendant’s platform.
`
`And Plaintiffs provide no answer to the obvious flaw in their theory of harm: DoorDash, the
`
`largest platform, does not use the challenged provisions, and restaurants and consumers are free
`
`to switch to that platform.
`
`As the opposition confirms, Counts I and III allege that the restrictions on restaurants
`
`charging higher menu prices on Defendants’ platforms than they do for items sold directly cause
`
`anticompetitive effects in the direct channels, where Defendants do not compete. Plaintiffs’ own
`
`precedent shows, however, that they must allege harm to a market in which Defendants do
`
`compete, and Plaintiffs do not—and cannot—allege that these restrictions reduce competition in
`
`the purportedly separate platform market. Plaintiffs’ arguments reveal their Catch-22 problem:
`
`the restrictions on higher restaurant pricing in the direct channels could harm competition only if
`
`meal-ordering platforms and restaurants’ direct channels were part of the same product market.
`
`But Plaintiffs have not pled such a market because Defendants would have a minuscule market
`
`share and their restrictions could not conceivably cause market-wide harm.
`
`Opposing dismissal of Counts II and IV, Plaintiffs repeat only conclusory allegations of
`
`anticompetitive effects in the platform channel from inter-platform NDPs that are allegedly in
`
`Uber Eats and Grubhub’s contracts. They do not address the disconnect between their assertion
`
`that Uber Eats and Grubhub force restaurants to accept inter-platform NDPs and their factual
`
`allegations suggesting that customers use multiple platforms interchangeably and that Uber Eats
`
`
`
`1
`
`

`

`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 42 Filed 01/19/21 Page 6 of 15
`
`
`
`and Grubhub compete with Postmates, DoorDash, and other platforms that do not use inter-
`
`platform NDPs.
`
`Plaintiffs’ claims should be dismissed with prejudice.
`
`I.
`
`PLAINTIFFS FAIL TO PLAUSIBLY ALLEGE COGNIZABLE
`ANTICOMPETITIVE EFFECTS IN THE “DIRECT” MARKETS (COUNT I).
`
`A.
`
`As a Matter of Law, Alleged Harm in the “Direct” Markets Is Insufficient
`Without Harm to Competition Among Meal-Ordering Platforms.
`
`Plaintiffs do not allege that Defendants compete in the “direct” markets. See Mem. 10-
`
`11. Nevertheless, in Count I, Plaintiffs allege that the contractual restrictions on restaurants
`
`charging higher menu prices on Defendants’ platforms than in the direct channels are unlawful
`
`because they harm competition in the direct channels. See Compl. ¶ 192. Count I should be
`
`dismissed because Plaintiffs do not—and cannot—plausibly allege that these restrictions reduce
`
`competition among meal-ordering platforms in the purported platform market. See Mem. 10-11.
`
`Plaintiffs cannot fix this fatal deficiency through their inapposite argument that they have
`
`antitrust standing because their alleged injury in the direct markets “was inextricably intertwined
`
`with the injury the conspirators sought to inflict.” Opp. 16-18.1
`
`The “inextricably intertwined” exception to the general rule that an antitrust plaintiff
`
`must be a “participant[] in the defendants’ market” addresses only “[t]he universe of potential
`
`plaintiffs.” In re Aluminum Warehousing Antitrust Litig., 833 F.3d 151, 158 (2d Cir. 2016). It
`
`does not address the substantive element of competitive harm, and thus does not absolve
`
`Plaintiffs of their obligation to plausibly allege that the NDPs reduce competition among meal-
`
`ordering platforms. Plaintiffs fail to cite a single case that survived a motion to dismiss where
`
`
`1 Count I—against all Defendants—does not challenge the inter-platform NDPs that are allegedly used
`only by Grubhub and Uber Eats, and not by Postmates.
`
`
`
`
`
`2
`
`

`

`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 42 Filed 01/19/21 Page 7 of 15
`
`
`
`the challenged agreement did not allegedly reduce competition among competitors in the
`
`defendants’ market, and they fail to distinguish the controlling caselaw (discussed in the moving
`
`brief) that Section 1 requires such harm. See Opp. 18 n.3.2 Rather, the cases Plaintiffs cite are
`
`consistent with this requirement because the conduct at issue in those cases was the “necessary”
`
`and “essential” “‘means’ to inflict injury on participants in the defendants’ market.” Aluminum,
`
`833 F.3d at 161-63 (emphasis added) (citation omitted); see id. at 159-63 (distinguishing Blue
`
`Shield of Virginia v. McCready, 457 U.S. 465 (1982), where the psychiatrists “accomplished
`
`their purported goal of harming the psychologists [competitors in the psychotherapy market] by
`
`inflicting direct harm on health insurance subscribers”).
`
`Plaintiffs’ allegation that the restrictions on menu pricing in the direct channels inhibit
`
`competition between each Defendant and its in-network restaurants, see Mem. 11; Opp. 16,
`
`could thus support a Section 1 claim only if restaurants and platforms competed in the same
`
`market, which Plaintiffs insist is not the case. Count I should be dismissed for this reason alone.
`
`B.
`
`Plaintiffs Fail to Directly or Indirectly Allege Anticompetitive Effects in the
`“Direct” Markets.
`
`Even if Plaintiffs could base Count I on harm to the direct channels, Plaintiffs do not
`
`point to any factual allegations of actual (direct) anticompetitive effects in the form of market-
`
`wide supracompetitive pricing in those channels. Repetition of narrow allegations about a study
`
`of New York restaurants that use GrubHub, see Opp. 22, does not suffice. See Mem. 12-13.
`
`
`2 Plaintiffs ignore that in Spinelli, the Second Circuit held that allegations of competitive harm in the
`market for “stock photography” were irrelevant because they “say nothing” about the market for
`“commercial licenses” in which defendants competed. See Spinelli v. NFL, 903 F.3d 185, 212 (2d Cir.
`2018); see also In re Zinc Antitrust Litig., 155 F. Supp. 3d 337, 365-77 (S.D.N.Y. 2016) (dismissing
`Section 1 claim for lack of plausible allegations of “anticompetitive agreement” in markets in which
`defendants competed). Plaintiffs also do not address the Ninth Circuit’s Qualcomm decision, see Mem.
`11, and in the case Plaintiffs cite involving multiple “relevant markets,” the defendants allegedly
`competed in each of those markets. See Prime Int’l Trading, Ltd. v. BP PLC, 784 F. App’x 4, 7 (2d Cir.
`2019) (defendants competed in both “relevant markets” for physical commodity and linked derivatives).
`
`
`
`3
`
`

`

`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 42 Filed 01/19/21 Page 8 of 15
`
`
`
`Plaintiffs also cannot plead anticompetitive effects indirectly because Defendants do not
`
`set any restaurant’s prices, have no market share, and have no market power in the direct
`
`channels. See Mem. 14-16. Plaintiffs do not argue to the contrary. See Opp. 16-24.
`
`Plaintiffs’ reliance on Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877
`
`(2007) to support their claims of anticompetitive effects, see Opp. 20-23, is misplaced. First, the
`
`NDPs are not resale price maintenance agreements; Defendants are platforms, not retailers, and
`
`the restaurants’ direct sales to consumers have no intermediary. Second, unlike the resale price
`
`maintenance agreements in Leegin, see id. at 21-22, the Complaint makes clear that NDPs set
`
`maximum prices, not minimum prices. Third, Plaintiffs’ allegations do not invoke either concern
`
`about retailer-led price restraints noted in Leegin—Plaintiffs do not allege a retailer cartel, and
`
`they do not allege that any Defendant is “dominant” (nor could they, given DoorDash’s position
`
`and all the new entrants to the marketplace). See 551 U.S. at 893, 897-98.
`
`Finally, even under Plaintiffs’ strained reading of Leegin, this case does not present the
`
`circumstances the Court identified in which vertical agreements might cause concern. Plaintiffs
`
`have not alleged facts sufficient to show that: (i) NDPs drive restaurants to charge uniform
`
`prices, see Mem. 12-14, 17-18; (ii) restaurants cannot forgo contracting with any individual
`
`Defendant, see id. at 14-16, 21-23; (iii) NDPs force the restaurants to charge supracompetitive
`
`prices to consumers, see id. at 12-14, 17-18; or (iv) that any Defendant possesses power in any
`
`market on the correct, transaction-share basis, see id. at 21; infra pp. 6-7.
`
`II.
`
`PLAINTIFFS FAIL TO PLAUSIBLY ALLEGE ANTICOMPETITIVE EFFECTS
`IN THE PURPORTED PLATFORM MARKET (COUNT II).
`
`A.
`
`Plaintiffs Fail to Allege That the Inter-Platform NDPs Cause Actual
`Anticompetitive Effects in the Purported Platform Market.
`
`In Count II, Plaintiffs challenge Grubhub and Uber’s inter-platform NDPs. They argue
`
`that without these restrictions, “restaurants could—and would—offer lower Restaurant List
`
`
`
`4
`
`

`

`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 42 Filed 01/19/21 Page 9 of 15
`
`
`
`Prices through Restaurant Platforms that offered lower Restaurant Commission Rates.” Opp. 25.
`
`They do not, however, make factual allegations that restaurants would switch to other platforms,
`
`or that menu prices would decrease, but for the inter-platform NDPs. See Mem. 17-18.
`
`Instead, Plaintiffs point to conclusory assertions and allegations that are insufficient to
`
`suggest market-wide anticompetitive effects. See Opp. 25 (citing Compl. ¶¶ 125-33). Plaintiffs
`
`treat their allegations regarding commissions and fees charged to customers as a proxy for
`
`elevated menu prices, see id. at 26 & n.7, but fees charged by platforms to consumers do not
`
`suggest that inter-platform NDPs in restaurant contracts caused restaurants to charge higher
`
`menu prices, see Compl. ¶¶ 43-45, 117. Tellingly, Plaintiffs fail to confront that in their main
`
`example of alleged higher menu prices, less than a quarter of New York restaurants raised prices
`
`at all. See Mem. 13. And even if Grubhub’s net prices allegedly increased over time and Uber
`
`and Grubhub have allegedly high profit margins, see Opp. 26, that does not suggest that
`
`restaurant menu prices have increased.
`
`The Complaint also does not support Plaintiffs’ argument that inter-platform NDPs cause
`
`market-wide anticompetitive effects because “a significant share of restaurants are bound” by
`
`those provisions. Id. at 26. As an initial matter, Plaintiffs have not plausibly pled the existence
`
`of supracompetitive prices. Further, Plaintiffs’ factual allegation about consumers multi-homing,
`
`see Mem. 22-23, belies their claim that restaurants must contract with Grubhub and Uber Eats
`
`(as opposed to DoorDash) to reach consumers. And even if Plaintiffs’ allegations about
`
`consumer use of platforms is correct, Compl. ¶ 86, that confirms only that at least a majority—
`
`and possibly up to 80%—of users on each platform do not use that platform exclusively.
`
`Plaintiffs’ assertion that inter-platform NDPs have “caused supracompetitive pricing in
`
`the form of inflated Restaurant Commission Rates,” Opp. 27-28, likewise fails. These
`
`
`
`5
`
`

`

`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 42 Filed 01/19/21 Page 10 of 15
`
`
`
`commissions are charged to restaurants, rather than to Plaintiff consumers. To the extent
`
`Plaintiffs assert that restaurants pass these higher rates on to consumers, the alleged restrictions
`
`on restaurants charging higher prices on Defendants’ platforms would prevent such pass-through.
`
`Finally, Plaintiffs’ attempt to assert anticompetitive effects in the form of reduced choice
`
`and quality, see id. at 24, is also insufficient. Their passing references to choice and quality, see
`
`Compl. ¶¶ 135-39, cobble together dated news stories, internet surveys, and anecdotes, and do
`
`not approach plausibly alleging that the inter-platform NDPs have caused a market-wide
`
`reduction in choice or quality. These assertions are also inconsistent with the factual allegations
`
`regarding the popularity and growth of meal-ordering platforms. See id. at ¶¶ 2, 52, 79.
`
`B.
`
`Plaintiffs Fail to Allege Durable Market Power or Other Indirect Indicia of
`Anticompetitive Effects in the Purported Platform Market.
`
`Plaintiffs do not allege facts suggesting that Grubhub and Uber Eats each possess durable
`
`market power in the platform market. See Mem. 19-23. Plaintiffs contend they have alleged
`
`such market power based on the number of restaurants that contract with each platform. See
`
`Opp. 29-30. But volume of transactions, not number of users, is the appropriate market share
`
`metric for two-sided transaction platforms. See Ohio v. Am. Express Co., 138 S. Ct. 2274, 2286
`
`& n.8 (2018) (because two-sided transaction platforms “cannot make a sale unless both sides of
`
`the platform simultaneously agree to use their services,” they “are best understood as supplying
`
`only one product—transactions”).
`
`Plaintiffs likewise cannot show durable market power based on a survey reporting market
`
`shares from a single month ranging from 20% to 31%. See Opp. 30. First, Plaintiffs ignore the
`
`
`
`6
`
`

`

`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 42 Filed 01/19/21 Page 11 of 15
`
`
`
`premise of the article from which they derive these shares,3 which is that Grubhub faces “tough
`
`competition” from many firms and a declining market share. Second, virtually all of the market
`
`shares pled are below the threshold typically required to state a Section 1 claim. See Com. Data
`
`Servers, Inc. v. Int’l Bus. Machs. Corp., 262 F. Supp. 2d 50, 74 (S.D.N.Y. 2003) (“Courts have
`
`consistently held that firms with market shares of less than 30% are presumptively incapable of
`
`exercising market power.” (citation omitted)). Third, Plaintiffs conspicuously omit that they
`
`have alleged a growing market and lots of entry, see Compl. ¶¶ 2, 15, 31, 110, belying their
`
`conclusory assertion of high barriers to entry. Plaintiffs’ cases, see Opp. 30, are not to the
`
`contrary because they involved higher market shares, horizontal conspiracies in addition to
`
`vertical agreements, and/or independent evidence of market power.4
`
`Finally, Plaintiffs’ assertion that they have pled “other evidence of Grubhub’s and Uber’s
`
`market power,” id. at 32-33, is largely duplicative of their arguments that they have pled direct
`
`evidence of anticompetitive effects, and they fail for the same reasons, see supra pp. 4-6.
`
`III.
`
`PLAINTIFFS FAIL TO ALLEGE A PLAUSIBLE RELEVANT MARKET
`(COUNTS I AND II).
`
`A.
`
`Plaintiffs Fail to Allege a Plausible Product Market.
`
`Plaintiffs agree that the test for pleading a plausible product market turns on the
`
`“interchangeability of use or the cross-elasticity of demand.” Mem. 23-24; Opp. 9. And
`
`
`3 Rani Molla, Grubhub sale rumors highlight the state of the struggling food-delivery industry, Vox (Jan.
`9, 2020), https://www.vox.com/recode/2020/1/9/21058674/grubhub-sale-food-delivery-struggling-
`industry.
`
`4 See R.J. Reynolds Tobacco Co. v. Cigarettes Cheaper!, 462 F.3d 690, 694-95 (7th Cir. 2006) (direct
`evidence of market power; 25% market share “irrelevant”); United States v. Visa U.S.A., Inc., 344 F.3d
`229, 239-40 (2d Cir. 2003) (combined 73% market share; direct evidence of market power); Toys "R" Us,
`Inc. v. FTC, 221 F.3d 928, 934, 937 (7th Cir. 2000) (concerted action; direct evidence of market power).
`Although Plaintiffs correctly note that Tops Markets, Inc. v. Quality Markets, Inc., 142 F.3d 90 (2d Cir.
`1998) concerned monopoly power, their cases do not endorse their proposed durable market share test.
`
`
`
`7
`
`

`

`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 42 Filed 01/19/21 Page 12 of 15
`
`
`
`Plaintiffs concede that ordering a meal from a restaurant can be a substitute for ordering the same
`
`meal over a meal-ordering platform. See Opp. 12. But Plaintiffs dispute that their factual
`
`allegations suggest that restaurants and meal-ordering platforms compete in the same market to
`
`sell takeout and delivery meals because: (i) meal-ordering platforms offer functionality that some
`
`restaurants choose not to offer, see id. at 10-11; (ii) there is “some,” but not enough cross-
`
`elasticity of demand between direct channels and meal-ordering platforms, id. at 11-13; and
`
`(iii) meal-ordering platforms “have profitably raised prices because not enough customers have
`
`switched to other products,” id. at 13. Each of these arguments is incorrect.
`
`First, that meal-ordering platforms offer some functionality that some restaurants choose
`
`not to offer does not justify separate markets, as “[r]easonable interchangeability fully
`
`acknowledges differences in product characteristics.” Mathias v. Daily News, L.P., 152 F. Supp.
`
`2d 465, 482 (S.D.N.Y. 2001). Like features that differentiate meal-ordering platforms from each
`
`other—e.g., consumer packages waiving monthly service fees, see Compl. ¶¶ 72-73—these
`
`differences suggest only that certain restaurants and meal-ordering platforms have chosen to
`
`compete for consumers’ orders by offering different services. This same rationale explains why,
`
`in Bookhouse, the court held that e-readers and physical books are part of the same product
`
`market even though unlike a physical book, an e-reader allows a consumer to instantly purchase,
`
`receive, and read a book electronically. See Bookhouse of Stuyvesant Plaza, Inc. v. Amazon.com,
`
`Inc., 985 F. Supp. 2d 612, 621 (S.D.N.Y. 2013).5
`
`
`5 The cases Plaintiffs cite are not to the contrary. In TSI Products, Inc. v. Armor All/STP Products Co.,
`the value-added kits had significant “uses separate from other products.” No. 3:18-cv-1682 (MPS), 2019
`WL 4600310, at *12-13 (D. Conn. Sept. 23, 2019). And in both Keurig and Meyer, the complaint at
`issue—unlike Plaintiffs’ claims here—provided factual allegations to support a narrowly-defined market.
`See 383 F. Supp. 3d 187, 226-27 (S.D.N.Y. 2019); Meyer v. Kalanick, 174 F. Supp. 3d 817, 827-28
`(S.D.N.Y. 2016).
`
`
`
`8
`
`

`

`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 42 Filed 01/19/21 Page 13 of 15
`
`
`
`Second, Plaintiffs fail to identify any factual allegation that contradicts the substantial
`
`alleged competition between the direct and platform channels, see Mem. 25, and that supports
`
`their assertion that cross-elasticity between the direct channels and platforms is “low.” Opp. 12.
`
`Third, as Plaintiffs acknowledge, an increase in meal-ordering platforms’ fees without
`
`substantial switching to direct channels does not suggest separate markets unless those fees were
`
`already supracompetitive and Defendants had substantial market power. See id. at 13. Plaintiffs
`
`have failed to plausibly allege either prerequisite. See supra pp. 4-7.
`
`Finally, Plaintiffs misinterpret the Supreme Court’s statement in American Express that
`
`“[o]nly other two-sided platforms can compete with a two-sided platform.” 138 S. Ct. at 2287.
`
`That might arguably be true with respect to the full complement of transactional services offered
`
`by a two-sided platform, but it does not change the fact that consumers seeking a meal choose
`
`interchangeably between options provided through the platforms and the options provided by the
`
`restaurants themselves. And Plaintiffs are incorrect that NDPs would be per se unlawful if meal-
`
`ordering platforms and direct channels comprise the same market, see Opp. 9, as the rule of
`
`reason applies to restraints in analogous dual-distribution arrangements. See Elecs. Commc’ns
`
`Corp. v. Toshiba Am. Consumer Prods., Inc., 129 F.3d 240, 243 (2d Cir. 1997).
`
`B.
`
` Plaintiffs Fail to Allege a Plausible National Platform Market.
`
` Plaintiffs argue that their proposed nationwide market is plausible because platforms
`
`allegedly have a few nationwide agreements with restaurant chains, and operate, advertise,
`
`provide similar user experiences, and charge the same fees nationwide. See Opp. 15. However,
`
`Plaintiffs fail to acknowledge that a relevant geographic market must consider “both the ‘area in
`
`which the seller operates, and to which the purchaser can practicably turn for supplies.’”
`
`Heerwagen v. Clear Channel Commc’ns, 435 F.3d 219, 230 (2d Cir. 2006) (citation omitted).
`
`Heerwagen rejected a substantively identical argument as the one Plaintiffs offer, and is
`
`
`
`9
`
`

`

`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 42 Filed 01/19/21 Page 14 of 15
`
`
`
`controlling. See id. at 230 (even though the defendant purportedly “conduct[ed] business and
`
`set[] prices at a national level,” the market for concert tickets was local, not national, because
`
`“only those people in a particular region are likely to buy tickets to concerts in that region”).6
`
`IV.
`
`PLAINTIFFS’ DERIVATIVE STATE LAW CLAIMS SHOULD BE DISMISSED
`(COUNTS III AND IV).
`
`Plaintiffs do not dispute that, if the Complaint fails to state a plausible Section 1 claim,
`
`then it also fails to state parallel claims under New York (or any state’s) antitrust law. See Opp.
`
`33-34. Rather, Plaintiffs contend that the NDPs are “minimum vertical price-fixing” agreements
`
`that “remain[] per se unlawful” under certain state laws. Id. But Counts III and IV do not even
`
`purport to allege per se claims—the phrase per se appears nowhere in the Complaint—and
`
`Plaintiffs cannot use their brief to amend the Complaint. See Wright v. Ernst & Young LLP, 152
`
`F.3d 169, 178 (2d Cir. 1998). In any event, this argument fails to salvage the state law claims
`
`because the NDPs do not set minimum resale prices. See supra p. 4. It also fails because the
`
`sole state in which Plaintiffs assert they have individual standing to bring a claim, New York,
`
`does not condemn such agreements as per se unlawful. See WorldHomeCenter.com, Inc. v. PLC
`
`Lighting, Inc., 851 F. Supp. 2d 494, 501-02 (S.D.N.Y. 2011); People v. Tempur-Pedic Int’l, Inc.,
`
`944 N.Y.S.2d 518, 519 (1st Dep’t 2012). Lacking plausible individual claims, Plaintiffs cannot
`
`assert claims based on other states’ laws. See Mem. 28-29.
`
`CONCLUSION
`
`For the foregoing reasons, each of Plaintiffs’ claims should be dismissed with prejudice.
`
`
`6 Each case Plaintiffs cite where courts found a nationwide market over the defendants’ objections
`involved contracts with consumers for sales on a nationwide basis. See, e.g., Heerwagen, 435 F.3d at 230
`(stating United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563 (1966) involved “nationwide contracts with
`customers”); Sentry Data Sys., Inc. v. CVS Health, 379 F. Supp. 3d 1320, 1328 (S.D. Fla. 2019) (CVS
`“contracts with covered entities for provision of 340B contract pharmacy services nationally”); see also
`New York v. Deutsche Telekom AG, 439 F. Supp. 3d 179, 203 (S.D.N.Y. 2020) (no dispute over
`nationwide geographic market).
`
`
`
`10
`
`

`

`Case 1:20-cv-03000-LAK Document 42 Filed 01/19/21 Page 15 of 15
`
`
`
`
`
`Dated: Washington, DC
`
`January 19, 2021
`
`/s/ Steven C. Sunshine
`Steven C. Sunshine
`SKADDEN, ARPS, SLATE,
` MEAGHER, & FLOM, LLP
`1400 New York Avenue N.W.
`Washington, D.C. 20005
`
`steve.sunshine@skadden.com
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Respectfully submitted,
`
`
`
`
`/s/ Derek Ludwin (with permission)
`Derek Ludwin
`Stacey K. Grigsby
`COVINGTON & BURLING LLP
`One CityCenter
`850 Tenth Street, N.W.
`Washington, D.C. 20001
`dludwin@cov.com
`sgrigsby@cov.com
`
`Andrew A. Ruffino
`COVINGTON & BURLING LLP
`620 Eighth Avenue
`New York, NY 10018
`aruffino@cov.com
`
`Counsel for Defendant Uber
`Technologies, Inc.
`
`
`/s/ David J. Lender (with permission)
`David J. Lender
`Eric S. Hochstadt
`WEIL, GOTSHAL & MANGES LLP
`767 Fifth Avenue
`New York, NY 10153
`david.lender@weil.com
`eric.hochstadt@weil.com
`
`Counsel for Defendant Grubhub Inc.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`Karen M. Lent
`Evan Kreiner
`SKADDEN, ARPS, SLATE,
` MEAGHER, & FLOM, LLP
`One Manhattan West
`
`New York, NY 10001
`
`karen.lent@skadden.com
`
`evan.kreiner@skadden.com
`
`Counsel for Defendant Postmates Inc.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`11
`
`

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket