throbber

`
`.
`.
`__-
`ELSEVIER
`
`Available online at www.5ciencedirectcom
`acmuc:
`urn-c1-
`
`@
`
`JOURNAL OF
`mm
`ECONOMICS
`
`Joumal of Health Economics 22 (2003) IS] —l85
`
`www.elsevier.enm/locate/econbasc
`
`The price of innovation: new estimates
`of drug development costs
`
`Joseph A. DiMasi“, Ronald W. Hansenb, Henry G. Grabowskic
`“ Tufts Centerfor the Study ofDmg Deielopment. Tufts University. 193 South Street.
`Suite 550. Boston. MA 021]]. l/Sl'l
`
`b William E. Simon Graduate School QfBusmers' Adminirlmlinn. lx'nivemityQfRochexter. Rochester: NY. USA
`c Department ofEconamics. Duke University Durham. NC US»!
`
`Received l7 January 2002‘. received in revised lbnn 24 May 2002: accepted 28 October 2002
`
`Abstract
`
`The research and development costs 0168 randomly selected new drugs were obtained from a sur-
`vey 01' l 0 pliannaceutical Iinns. These data were used to estimate the average pre-tax cost ofnew drug
`development. The costs of compounds abandoned during testing were linked to the costs of com-
`pounds thut obtained marketing approval. The estimated average out-of-pocket cost per new drug is
`US$ 403 million (2000 dollars). Capitalizing out-of-poeket costs to the point of marketing approval
`at a real discount rate OH 1% yields a total pre-approval cost estimate ofUS$ 802 million (2000 dol-
`lars). When compared to the results ol'an earlier study mm a similar methodology, total capitalized
`costs were shovm to have increased at an annual rate ot’7.4% above general price inflation.
`C 2003 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.
`
`JEL classification: L65; 031
`
`Kgmiords: Innovation: R&D cost: Pharmaceutical industry: Discount rate. Technical success rates
`
`
`l. lntmduction
`
`Innovations in the health sciences have resulted in dramatic changes in the ability to treat
`disease and improve the quality of life. Expenditures on phamiaceuticals have grown faster
`than other major components of the health care system since the late 19905. Consequently.
`the debates on rising health care costs and thc dcvclopmcnt of new medical technologies
`have focused increasingly on the pharmaceutical industry. which is botha major participant
`in the health care industry and a major source of advances in health care technologies.
`
`‘ Corresponding author. 'l‘el.: +1-617-636-2l 16.
`E-mail address;josepll.dirnasi@tulls.edu (IA. DiMasi).
`
`see front matter £3“ 2003 Elsevier Science B.\’. All rights reserved.
`0167-6296503/5
`doi: 10. IO] 6v’SOl67~6296(02)00 l 26-]
`
`Exhbit 2067
`Slayback v. Sumitomo
`IPR2020—01053
`
`

`

`l52
`
`in. Dnllari e! at. Journal ofllealrh Economics 22 2003) 1517 185
`
`One of the key components of the discussion is the role of private sector phamtaeeutical
`industry investments in R&D and an understanding of the factors that affect this process.
`Although the industry engages in many forms of innovation. in general the most significant
`is the discovery and development of new chemical and biopharrnaceutical entities that
`become new therapies. Our prior research (DiMasi et al.. I991) found that the discovery
`and development of new drugs is a very lengthy and costly process. In the research-based
`drug industry. R&D decisions have very long-term ramifications. and the impact of market
`or public policy changes may not be fully realized for many years. From both a policy
`perspective. as well as an industrial perspective. it is therefore important to continue to
`analyve the components of and trends in the costs of pharmaceutical innovation.
`In this paper we will build on research conducted by the cunent authors (DiMasi et al..
`1991) and others on the economics of pharmaceutical R&D. As we described in our prior
`study. "Empirical analyses of the cost to discover and develop NCEs are interesting on
`several counts. First. knowledge of R&D costs is important for analyzing issues such as
`the returns on R&D investment. Second. the cost of a new drug has direct bearing on
`the organizational structure of innovation in pharmaceuticals. In this regard. higher real
`R&D costs have been cited as one of the main factors underlying the recent trend toward
`more mergers and industry consolidation. Third. R&D costs also influence the pattern
`of international resource allocation. Finally. the cost of R&D has become an important
`issue in its own right in the recent policy deliberations involving regulatory requirements
`and the economic performance of the pharmaceutical industry". In the decade that has
`followed the publication of our earlier study. these issues remain paramount. In addition.
`the congressional debates on Medicare prescription drug coverage and various new state
`initiatives to fill gaps in coverage for the elderly and the uninsured have intensified the
`interest in the performance of the pharmaceutical industry.
`In the current study we are not attempting to directly answer the policy debates men-
`tioned above. Rather. our focus is on providing new estimates of economic parameters
`associated with the drug development process. In particular. we concentrate on estimates
`of the costs of phamraceutical innovation. Our prior estimates have been used by the Office
`of Technology assessment (OTA). the Congressional Budget Office (CBO). and various
`researchers to analyze policy questions such as the effects on R&D activities of health care
`financing reform or changes in intellectual property legislation related to the phamiaceutical
`industry.
`The approach used in this paper follows our previous study (DiMasi et al.. 1991) and
`the earlier work by Hansen (1979). Given the similarity in methodologies. we are able
`to compare our results in the current study with the estimates in the earlier studies to
`illustrate trends in development costs. All three studies used micro-level data on the cost
`and timing of development obtained thrOugh confidential surveys of plannaceutical firms
`for a random sample of new drugs first investigated in humans by these firms. In the current
`study. the new drugs were first tested in humans anywhere in the world between 1983 and
`1994. The reported development costs ran through 2000.Ultimately. we are interested in
`the expected cost of development per approved new drug. The uncertainties in the research
`and development process result in expenditures on many development projects that are not
`successful in producing a marketed product. However. to produce an estimate of expected
`cost for a marketed product. we must allocate the costs of the unsuccessful projects to those
`
`

`

`J11. Dill-last et al. "Journal ofHealth Economics 22 (2003) I51 I85
`
`153
`
`that result in a marketed new product. The R&D process is lengthy. and as such it is important
`to know at what stage of development expenses occur. Viewed as an investment project. it
`is necessary to know both the amountof expenditures and the timing of these expenditures.
`since funds committed to R&D in advance of any returns from sales have both a direct
`and an opportunity cost. We used a unique database to estimate various cost parameters
`in the development process. Of particular concern is the estimation of the average pre-tay
`cost of new drug development. since we are interested in the resource costs of new drug
`development and how they have changed over time.
`
`I. 1. Previous studies ofthe cost ofpharmaceutical innovation
`
`A summary of early studies of the cost of drug development can be found in the authors’
`previous study miMasi ct al.. 1991) and in OTA (1993). In brief. the early studies were
`either based on a case study of a specific drug (usually ignoring the cost of failed projects)
`or relied on aggregate data. Since the R&D process often extends for a decade or more
`and the new drug development process often changes. it is difficult to estimate the cost
`of development from aggregated annual data. In contrast. the study by Hansen (1979)
`and the current authors’ previous study (DiMasi et al.. 1991) estimated development cost
`based on data supplied by firms for a representative sample of drug development
`efforts.
`
`DiMasi ct al. (1991) used data on self-originated new drugs to estimate the average cost
`of developing a new drug. They obtained data from 12 pharmaceutical firms on the research
`and development costs of 93 randomly selected new drugs that entered clinical trials be-
`tween l970 and 1982. From these data they estimated the average pre-tav out-of-pocket
`cost per approved drug to be US$ 114 million (1987 dollars). Since these expenditures
`were spread out over nearly a dozen years. they capitalized these expenditures to the date
`of marketing approval using a 9% discount rate. This yielded an estimate of US$ 231
`million (1987 dollars). Measured in constant dollars. this value is more than double that
`obtained by Hansen for an earlier sample. DiMasi ct al. (1991) also found that the average
`cost of the first two phases of clinical trials doubled between the first and second half of
`their sample. This led to the expectation that development costs would be higher in future
`samples.
`Based on an analysis by Myers and Shyam-Sunder performed for the OTA. the OTA
`(1993) report noted that the cost-of-capital for the industry was roughly 10% in the early
`[9805. This is moderately higher than the 9% used by DiMasi et al. (1991). The OTA also
`recalculated the DiMasi et al. (1991) numbers using an interest rate that varied over the life
`of the R&D cycle thereby raising the cost estimate by US$ 100 million in 1990 dollars.1
`The OTA presented both pre- and post-tax cost estinmes.
`
`
`' The OTA applied a range of discount rates that varied with the time to marketing approval. They chose 14%
`for the earliest stage R&D and 10% for development just prior to approval. with rates in between that declined
`linearly With time in development. 'lhrs approach was meant to capture the essence of the risk-return staircase
`perspective expressed by Myers and others. and discussed below. The methodology described in Myers and liowe
`(1997) is actually quite different. but the OTA technique yielded results that would not be much different (for the
`same distribution of costs) than what one would have obtained with the correct methodology (Myers and Howe.
`1997. p. 33).
`
`

`

`154
`
`JA. Dbl-last et (11. "Journal ofHeaIth Economics 22 (2003) I51 .185
`
`
`
`1963 1967 1971 1975 1979 1983 1987 1991 1995 1999
`
`- NCEs +Real R&D (20003) ——~crs Trend
`
`28
`
`243
`g
`
`165
`3
`122M
`
`8 §
`4 Q
`
`0
`
`Fig. 1. Inflation-adjusted industry R&D expenditures (2000 dollars) and US new chemical entity (N'CE) approvals
`from 1963 to 2000. Source ol'data: l’hRMA (2001) and 'l'ut‘Ls CS DI) Approved NCF. Database.
`
`1.2. Aggregate dam wraivses
`
`There have been no recent comprehensive studies of the cost of developing new pharma-
`ceuticals from synthesis to marketing approval based on actual project-level data. However.
`aggregate data and data on parameters of the drug development process suggest that R&D
`costs have increased substantially since our earlier study. For example. the Pharmaceutical
`Research and Manufacturers of America (PhRMA. 2000) publishes an annual report on the
`R&D expenditures of its member firms that shows a continuous increase in outlays well in
`excess of inflation. Reports on specific components of the R&D process. such as the number
`of subjects in clinical trials (OTA. 1993: The Boston Consulting Group [ECG]. 1993). also
`suggest an increase in the real cost of pharmaceutical innovation.
`1
`Published aggregate industry data suggest that R&D costs have been increasing. Fig.
`shows reported aggregate annual domestic prescription drug R&D expenditures for mem-
`bers of the US pharmaceutical industry since 1963. The chart also shows the number of
`US new drug approvals by year. Given the much faster rate of growth of R&D expendi-
`tures. data such as these suggest that R&D costs have increased over time. However. they
`cannot be conclusive or precise. For one matter. the drug development process is known
`to be very lengthy. Thus. new drug approvals today are associated with R&D expenditures
`that were incurred many years prior. Ignoring the inherent lag structure underlying these
`data and simply dividing current R&D expenditures by the number of new drug approvals
`will in general yield inaccurate estimates? Given a substantial increasing trend in R&D
`
`2 lhe estimates would also vary widely from year-to-year. For example. if we divrded each year's real R&D
`expenditures by that year‘s nlunber of NC}: apprmals. we would obtain [83 1 billion for 2000, U83 743 million
`for I999. USS 839 million for 1998. USS 568 million for l997. USS 400 million for I996. USS 635 million for
`I995. and [SS R78 million for I994. While there is a general upward trend in such calculations. the year-to-year
`variability is not credible.
`
`

`

`in. Dill-last et at. "Journal ofHealth Economics 22 (2003) I51 I85
`
`l55
`
`expenditures. such calculations will result in greatly exaggerated estimates of out-of-pocket
`cost per approval.
`Secondly. even properly lagged time series would tend to be imprecise if aggregate in-
`dustry data were used as reported. The industry data include expenditures on improvements
`to existing products. Thus. they would overestimte pro-approval development costs. On
`the other hand. they also do not incorporate all of the R&D on licensed-in drugs since
`firms or other organi7ations that are not members of the US trade association would have
`conducted some of the work. On that account the data would tend to underestimate costs.
`
`Therefore. R&D cost estimates based on project-level data are needed to assure a reasonable
`level of confidence in the accuracy of the results. We present results based on such data in
`this study.
`The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the standard
`drug development paradigm. which serves as the structure through which the results are
`reported. Section 3 contains a description ofthe survey sample data and the population from
`which it was drawn. Section 4 describes the methodology used to derive R&D cost esti-
`mates. We present our base case pre-marketing approval R&D cost estimates in Section 5.
`as well as a comparison of our results with those of earlier studies to examine R&D cost
`trends. Section 6 provides sensitivity analyses for key parameters. Section 7 focrses on
`some extensions of the base case analyses: estimates of clinical development costs for ap-
`proved drugs by therapeutic significance. estimates of post-approval R&D costs. and a tax
`analysis. Section 8 contains data and analyses that corroborate our results. Finally. we offer
`some conclusions in Section 9.
`
`2. The new drug development process
`
`New dmg development can proceed along varied pathways for different compounds. but
`a development paradigm has been articulated that has long served well as a general model.
`The paradigm is explained in some detail elsewhere (DiMasi ct al.. 1991: US Food and Drug
`Administration [FDA]. 1999). In outline form, the paradigm portrays new drug discovery
`and development as proceeding in a sequence of (possibly overlapping) phases. Discovery
`programs result in the synthesis of compounds that are tested in assays and animal models.
`It was not possible to disaggregate our data into discovery and preclinical development
`testing costs.3 so for the purposes of this study discovery and preclinical development costs
`are grouped and referred to as preclinical costs.
`Clinical (human) testing typically proceeds through three successive phases. In phase I.
`a small number of usually healthy volunteers4 are tested to establish safe dosages and to
`gatherinforrnation on the absorption. distribution. metabolic effects. excretion. and toxicity
`of the compound. To conduct clinical testing in the United States. a manufacturer must first
`
`3 The reported basic research expenditures by firm were highly variable. and suggest that different firms may
`categorize their pre-human testing expenditures somewhat difl‘ererrtly. Thus. we report pre-human testing costs in
`one figure.
`4 in some therapeutic areas, testing is initially done on patients who have the disease or condition for which the
`compound is intended to be a treatment. This is ordinarily true in the cancer and AIDS areas.
`
`

`

`156
`
`JA. Dill-last et at. "Journal ofHealth Economics 22 (2003) I51 185
`
`file an investigational new drug application (IND) with the FDA. However. initiation of
`human testing can. and ofien does. occur first outside the United States.
`Phase II trials are conducted with subjects who lave the targeted disease or condition
`and are designed to obtain evidence on safety and preliminary data on efficacy. The number
`of subjects tested in this phase is larger than in phase land may number in the hundreds.
`The final pre-approval clinical testing phase. phase III, typically consists of a number of
`large-scale (often multi-center) trials that are designed to firmly establish efficacy and to
`uncover side-effects that occur infrequently. The number of subjects in phase III trials for
`a compound can total in the thousands.
`Once drug developers believe that they have enough evidence of safety and efficacy.
`they will compile the results of their testing in an application to regulatory authorities
`for marketing approval. In the United States. manufacturers submit a new drug appli-
`cation (NDA) or a biological lieeme application (BLA) to the FDA for review and
`approval.
`
`3. Data
`
`Ten multinational pharmaceutical firms. including both foreign and US-owned firms.
`provided data through a confidential survey of their new dnig R&D costs.S Data were
`collected on clinical phase costs for a randomly selected sample of the investigational drugs
`of the fimis participating in the survey.6 The sample was taken from a Tufts Center for the
`Study of Drug Development (CSDD) database of investigational compounds. Cost and time
`data were also collected for expenditures on the kind of animal testing that often occurs
`concunently with clinical trials.7 The compounds chosen were all self-originated; that is.
`their development up to initial regulatory marketing approval was conducted under the
`auspices of the surveyed firm.8 Licensed-in compounds were excluded becarrse non-survey
`firms would have conducted portions of the R&D.9
`We also collected data from the cost survey participants on their aggregate annual phar-
`maceutical R&D expenditures for the period 1980—1999. The firms reported on total an-
`nual R&D expenditures broken down by expenditures on self-originated new dnigs. on
`licensed-in or otherwise acquired new drugs. and on already-approved dnigs. Annual ex-
`penditures on self-originated new drugs were further decomposed into expenditures during
`the pre-human and clinical periods.
`The National Institutes of Health (NIH) support through their own labs and through grants
`to researchers in academic and other non-profit institutions a substantial amount of research
`
`
`5 Using phannaceutical sales to measure lirrn size, four of the survey firms are top 10 companies. mother four
`are among the next IO largest fimts. and the remaining two are outside the top 20 (P513. 2000).
`‘5 A copy of the survey instrument is available upon request.
`7 long—tenn teratogenicity and carcinogenicity testing may he conducted aiter the initiation ofclinical trials.
`8 lhis does not preclude situations in which the firm sponsors trials that are conducted by or in collaboration
`with a govemment agency. an individual or group in academia. a non-profit institute. or another firm.
`9 Large pharmaceutical finns much more otten license-in than license-out new drug candidates. Firms that
`license-in compounds for further development pay a price for that right through up-front fees. milestone payments.
`and royalty arrangements.
`
`

`

`Jxl. Dill/last et (.11. «Journal ofHeaIrh Economics 22 (2003) I51 ~l85
`
`l 57
`
`that expands fundamental knowledge about human biology (NIH. 2000: Scherer. 2000).
`This basic research sometimes results in leads that industrial researchers can capitaliye
`on to assist them in discovering new therapeutic compounds.10 Some new compounds
`investigated by phamiaceutical fimis, however. originated in goverrunent or academic labs.
`It is unclear whether the discovery and early development costs for such compounds are
`similar to those for compounds originating in industrial labs. These drugs. though. represent
`a very small portion of the total number developed. For example. NIH (2000) found that
`of 47 FDA-approved drugs that had reached at least USS 500 million in US sales in 1999.
`the government had direct or indirect use or ownership patent rights to only four of them.“
`In addition. we used a Tufts CSDD database supplemented by commercial databases to
`determine that of the 284 new drugs approved in the United States from 1990 to 1999.12
`3.3% originated from industrial sources (either from the sponsoring firm or from another
`firm from which the compound was licensed or otherwise acquired). Government sources
`accounted for 3.2% of these approvals and academia and other non-profits accounted for
`the other 3.5%. ‘3
`The survey firms accounted for 42% of pharmaceutical industry R&D expenditures.”
`The survey compounds were selected at random from data contained in the Tufts CSDD
`database of imv'estigational compounds for the firms that agreed to participate in the R&D
`cost survey. Of the 68 compounds chosen. 61 are small molecule chemical entities. fourare
`recombinant proteins, two are monoclonal antibodies, and one is a vaccine. Initial human
`testing anywhere in the world for these compounds occurred during the period 1983—1994.
`Development costs were obtained through 2000.15
`
`'0 The NIH also supports the development ol'research tools that drug developers find useful. In addition. it funds
`training for many scientists. some of whom eventually are employed in the industrial sector.
`” lhe four dnrgs were developed in part through the use of NIH-funded patented technologies. Three of the
`four products are recombinant proteins. with two being the same drug produced by two dillerent companies. Each
`of the relevant patented teclurologies was developed at academic or non-profit institutions with financial suppon
`from the NIH.
`
`'2 The definition ot‘a new drug used for this analysis is a therapeutic new molecular entity approved by the F DA‘s
`Center for Dmg Evaluation and Research.
`'3 lhe proportion of investigational drugs that derive from industrial sources is likely to be even higher. since
`acquired drugs have higher clinical approval success rates than do self-originated drugs (Dr-Mam. 2001b). Our
`cost sm‘vcy linns were less reliant on licensing-in drugs from non-industrial sources than were firms as a whole;
`98.8% oftheir new drug approvals during 1990— 1999 were from industrial sources. DiMasi (2000) found markedly
`greater market entry of small niche pharmaceutical firms in the 19905 relative to earlier periods as measured by
`sponsorship of new chemical entity (NCE) approvals. A disproportionate share ofthe approvals obtained by these
`new entrants was for drugs that originated in academia.
`"' The data used were aggregate firm pharmaceutical R&D expenditures for the cost survey firms. as reported
`on our questiorurainr. in comparison to I’hRMA member firm R&D expenditures (1994 1997) on ethical phanna-
`ceuticals, adjusted to global expenditure levels (PhRMA. 2001).
`'5 Surveys were sent to 24 firms (some of. whom have since merged). Twelve finns responded that they would
`panicipate in some form. The data that two firms ultimately provided were not useable. The 10 firms from which
`we used data provided information on 76 compounds. However. the data for eight of these compounds were not
`sufficiently comprehensive to use. The firms that did not participate in the survey cited a number of reasons for
`not doing so. The reasons included the extra demands that the transition ell‘ects oI‘a relatively recent merger were
`placing on their relevant personnel. the time and expense of retrieving archival records in the manner required by
`the study, and difiiculties in gathering the relevant data in a uniform manner because their accounting systems had
`changed sigiificantly over the study period
`
`

`

`158
`
`JA. DIA-las/ et (11. «Journal ofHealth Economics 22 (2003) 151 185
`
`We selected a stratified random sample of investigational compounds. Stratification was
`based on the time elapsed since the origination of clinical trials and the current status of
`that testing. Reported costs were weighted to reflect the characteristics of the population.
`so that knowledge of the population from which the sample was drawn was needed. The
`population is composed of all investigational compounds in the Tufts CSDD investigational
`drug database that met study criteria: the compounds were self-originated and first tested in
`humans anywhere in the world from [983 to 1994. and we had the information necessary
`to classify them according our strata. We found 538 imrestigational drugs that met these
`criteria. Of these compounds. 82 (15.2%) have been approved for marketing. 9 (1.7%) had
`NDAs or BLAs that were submitted and are still active. 5 (0.9%) had NDAs or BLAs
`submitted but abandoned. 227 (42.2%) were terminated in 4 years or less from the initiation
`of clinical trials. 172 (32.0%) were terminated more than 4 years after the start of clinical
`testing. and 43 (8.0%) were still in active testing as of the most recent check (31 March
`2001).
`Some firms were not able to provide full phase cost data for every new dnig sampled.
`For example. phase I cost data were available for 66 of the 68 new drugs. However. we
`lmd some phase cost data for every drug in the sample. In addition. five compounds were
`still active at the time of the study. For these drugs it is possible that there will be some
`future costs for the drug’s most recent phase. Thus. for this reason our cost estimates may
`be somewhat conservative. However. given the small number of drugs in this category and
`the fact that the impact would be on only one phase for each of these drugs, our overall cost
`estimates are not likely to be materially alTectcd.
`
`4. Methodology for estimating new drug development costs
`
`The approach that we use to estimate development costs is similar to that described in
`our earlier work (DiMasi et al.. 1991). We will outline here the general methodology for
`developing an overall cost estimate. In describing the approach. it will be clear that cost
`estimates for important components of the drug development process will also be derived
`along the way.
`The survey sample was stratified to reduce sampling error. Results from previous anal-
`yses suggested that the variability of drug costs tends to increase with the development
`phase or the amount of time that a drug spends in testing (Hansen. 1979: DiMasi ct al..
`1991). Costs for successful drugs (ie. those that achieve regulatory approval) also tend to
`be higher and more variable than those for drug failures. Thus. we based our strata on the
`length of time that failed compounds were in clinical testing and whether or not a compound
`had reached the stage in which an application for marketing approval had been filed with
`the FDA.
`
`'° Specifically. we used four strata: compounds that failed in 4 years or less of clinical testing: corrpomds that
`failed alter more than 4 years had elapsed from initial human testing: compounds for which an NDA or a BLA had
`been submitted to the FDA; and compounds that were still in active testing (as of 30 March 2001 ). Compounds
`for which an application for marketing approval had been submitted or which had been abandoned afier lengthy
`testing were deliberately oversampled. The reported sample values were then weighted. where the weights were
`determined so that the sample perfectly reflects the population in terns of the four strata.
`
`

`

`in. Dbl-last et (11. "Journal ofHeaItir Economics 22 (2003) I51 .185
`
`l59
`
`4.]. Expected costs in the clinical period
`
`Since new drug development is a risky process. with many compounds failing for every
`one that succeeds. it is necessary to analyze costs in expected value terms. The total clinical
`period cost for an individual drug can be viewed as the realization of a random variable. 6.
`Given that it is not certainthat development ofa randomly selected investigational compound
`will proceed to a given phase. we may define expected clinical costs for a randomly selected
`investigational drug to be C = E (c) = PWIIc + pu/tmc-l- put/11mg + pAuAlc. where p1. Pu.
`and pin. are the probabilities that a randomly selected investigational compound will enter
`phases I—III. respectively. pA the probability that long-term animal testing will be conducted
`during the clinical trial period. and the ,u’s are conditional expectations. Specifically. it“...
`ttulc. urine. and [LAlc are the population mean costs for drugs that enter phases H“. and
`clinical period long-term animal testing, respectively.
`Weighted mean phase costs derived from the cost survey data were used to estimate the
`conditional expectations. A description of how the probabilities were estimated is presented
`in the next section. Assuming that the estimated mean phase costs and success probabilities
`are stochastically independent. the estimated expected value is an unbiased estimate of the
`population expected value.
`
`4.2. Clinical success and phase attrition rates
`
`An overall clinical approval success rate is the probability that a compound that enters the
`clinical testing pipeline will eventually be approved for marketing. Attrition rates describe
`the rate at which investigational dmgs fall out of testing in the various clinical phases. A
`phase success rate is the probability that a dmg will attain marketing approval if it enters the
`given phase. A phase transition probability is the likelihood that an investigational drug will
`proceed in testing front one phase to the next. All of these probabilities can be estimated
`from data in the Tufts CSDD database of investigational drugs from which our survey
`sample was drawn.
`The clinical approval success rate was estimated using a two-stage statistical estimation
`process that has been described in detail elsewhere (DiMasi etal.. 1991: DiMasi. 200 lb). The
`data used here consist of the investigatioml drugs in the Tufts CSDD database that were first
`tested in humans anywhere in the world from 1983 to 1994. with information on their status
`(approval or research abandonment) obtained through early 2001. Given that some of these
`investigational drugs were still in active testing at the end of the study period. some of the
`data are right-censored. Survival analysis can be applied in such a situation. where survival
`indicates that a drug has not reached its ultimate fate (either approval or abandonment).
`The Tufts CSDD database of investigational compounds contains infomiation on the
`latest phase that an abandoned compound was in when it was tenninated. These data were
`used to determine the distribution of research terminations by phases.” These results.
`
`'7 A small proportion of the compounds in the database were either still in clinical development (8.0%) orhad
`an NDA or BIA filed but not yet approved ( l .796). For those drugs in these groups that will eventually fail. their
`abandonment will tend to occur in later testing phases. To deal with the potential bias in the estimated distribution
`of research terminations that would result from usingjust these compounds that had been abandoned by the end of
`
`

`

`[60
`
`JA. Dill-last et al. «Journal ofHealth Economics 22 (2003) I51 18.5
`
`together with the estimated overall clinical approval success rate were used to provide
`estimates of the probability that an investigational drug will enter a given phase. phase
`attrition rates. and phase transition probabilities. The estimated overall clinical approval
`success rate and the probabilities of entering various phases provide results with which
`estimates can be derived that include the cost of dnigs that fail to make it through the
`development process. Specifically, we use the probabilities of entering a phase to estimate
`the expected out-of-pocket clinical cost per investigational drug. Adding the out-of-pocket
`preclinical cost estimate described below yields an estimate of total out-of-pocket cost per
`investigational drug. Dividing this estimate by the overall clinical success rate yields our
`estimate of out-of-pocket cost per approved drug.
`
`4. 3. Out-of—pocket discovery and preclinical development costs
`
`Many costs incurred prior to clinical testing cannot be attributed to specific compounds.
`Thus. aggregate level data at the firm level were used to impute costs per drug for R&D
`incurred prior to human testing. Specifically. time series data for each surveyed firm on
`spending on pre-human R&D and on human testing for 1980—1999 were o

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket