throbber
No. 17-204
`
`In the
`Supreme Court of the United States
`
`Apple INc.,
`
`v.
`
`RobeRt peppeR, et al.,
`
`Petitioner,
`
`Respondents.
`
`On Writ Of CertiOrari tO the United StateS
`COUrt Of appealS fOr the ninth CirCUit
`
`Brief of ACT | The App AssoCiATion
`As Amicus curiAe in supporT
`of peTiTioner
`
`BrIan ScarpellI
`Counsel of Record
`Joel thayer
`act | the app aSSocIatIon
`1401 K Street, NW, Suite 501
`Washington, DC 20005
`(517) 507-1446
`bscarpelli@actonline.org
`jthayer@actonline.org
`
`Counsel for Amicus Curiae
`
`283125
`
`A
`
`(800) 274-3321 • (800) 359-6859
`
`

`

`i
`
`tAble oF coNteNtS. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . i
`
`tAble oF cIteD AUtHoRItIeS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . iii
`
`INteReSt oF AmiCus CuRiAe . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .1
`
`SUmmARy oF ARgUmeNt . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .2
`
`ARgUmeNt . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .5
`
`I. the Ninth circuit Factually Ignoring the
`procompetitive Agency-Sale Relationship
`App Developers Have with App Stores
`Fatally Skews its Reasoning and conclusions. . .5
`
`
`
`A. t he benef it s of the sy mbiot ic
`relationship between app developers
`and app platforms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .7
`
`
`
`1. platforms lower overhead costs that
`simplify market entry . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .7
`
`
`2. platforms give app developers
`instant access to international
` markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .11
`
`3. before platforms, app developers
`struggled to build trust with end
`users. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .11
`
`
`
`TABle of ConTenTs
`
`Page
`
`

`

`ii
`
`4. platforms strengthen intellectual
`property protections for app
`developers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .13
`
`
`
`b. by Ignoring the Roles of market
`participants in the App economy, the
`Ninth circuit’s Functional Approach
`of the Direct Sellers Rule Implicitly
`categorizes petitioner as a Reseller of
`all Apps it Hosts on its platform . . . . . . . .15
`
`
`
`II. the Ninth circuit misapplies illinois
`Brick, and Would Allow consumers to
`Interject into the platform and App
`Developer business Relationship . . . . . . . . . . . .18
`
`
`
`coNclUSIoN . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .24
`
`Table of Contents
`
`Page
`
`

`

`iii
`
`CAses
`
`Dastar Corp. v.
`Twentieth Century Fox Film Corp.,
`539 U.S. 23 (2003). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .1
`
`
`
`Delaware Valley surgical supply, inc. v.
`Johnson & Johnson,
`523 F.3d 1116 (9th Cir. 2008). . . . . . . . . . . . . .20, 21, 23
`
`
`
`Hanover shoe, inc. v.
`united shoe machinery Corp.,
`392 U.S. 481 (1968). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .18, 19
`
`
`
`illinois Brick Co. v. illinois,
`431 U.S. 720 (1977). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . passim
`
`
`in re Apple iPhone Antitrust Litig.,
`846 F.3d 313 (9th Cir. 2017). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .20, 21
`
`
`in re Apple iPhone Antitrust Litig.,
` No. 11-CV-06714-YGR, 2013 WL 6253147
`(N.D. cal. Dec. 2, 2013), rev’d and remanded
`sub nom. in re Apple iPhone Antitrust Litig.,
`846 F.3d 313 (9th Cir. 2017). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .19, 21
`
`
`
`Kansas v. utiliCorp united, inc.,
`497 U.S. 199 (1990) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .16
`
`
`Petrella v. metro-Goldwyn-mayer, inc.,
`134 S. Ct. 1962 (2014) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .1
`
`
`TABle of CiTeD AuThoriTies
`
`Page
`
`

`

`iv
`
`united states v. microsoft Corp.,
`
`253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .1
`
`sTATuTes AnD oTher AuThoriTies
`
`15 U.S.C. § 15(a) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .15
`
`Rule 12(b)(6) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .15
`
`Act | the App Association, The symbiotic
`Relationship Between App Developers
`and Platforms: A Ten-Year Retrospect,
` Website (last checked, August 7, 2018) . . . . . . . . . . .21
`
`Adam Jaffe & benjamin Jones, The Changing
`F r o n t i e r : R e t h i n k i n g s c i e n c e a n d
`innovation Policy, National bureau of
` Economic Research (2015) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .9
`
`Dan Russell-pinson, OmG! someone Copied
`my Ap p. W h at Do i Do No w?, a c t
`| the app aSSocIatIon (August 30, 2017) . . . . . . .14
`
`
`
`Deloitte, The App economy of the united
`states: A Rev iew of the mobil e Ap p
`market its Contribuiton to the united
` states, Report (forthcoming 2018) . . . . . . . . . . .7, 8, 10
`
`Cited Authorities
`
`Page
`
`

`

`v
`
`erik brynjolfssn & michael Smith, Frictionless
`Commerce? A Comparison of internet
` and Conventional Retailers, MIT (1999) . . . . . . . . .12
`
`H u g o D e l g a d o , T h e A p p e c o n o m y
`Forecast: A $6 Trillion market in the
` making, App Annie (2017) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .11, 22
`
`K e l l y Jo h n s o n S w a n , un i t e d s t a t e s :
`The Tr ue Cost of Defending Against
`Co p yr i gh t inf r in ge m e n t Li ti ga ti o n ,
` Scott & Scott LLP (August 19, 2015) . . . . . . . . . . . .14
`
`Ket a n p r at ap, Ap pl e says De vel o p e r s
`earned Over $70 Billion since App store’s
` Launch, Gadget 360 (Jun. 1, 2017). . . . . . . . . . . . . . .11
`
`milton Handler, Changing Trends in Antitrust
`Doctrines: An unprecedented supreme Court
` Term—1977, 77 Colum. L. Rev. 979 (1977) . . . . . . . .16
`
`Roya Stephens & Adarsh mahesh, state of the App
` economy, Act | the App Association (2018) . . . .3, 5
`
`Sarah perez, Paid Apps on the Decline: 90% of
`iOs Apps Are Free, up From 80-84% During
`2010 -2012 , says Flur r y, techcr unch
`(Jul. 18, 2013). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .22
`
`
`
`Cited Authorities
`
`Page
`
`

`

`vi
`
`Steve yo ung, making $1.5 million with
`educatio nal Ap ps w ith Pier re Abel,
` App Masters (Apr. 30, 2015) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .10
`
`Stew chyou, The History of shareware,
` Thunderbolt (May 5, 2011) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .12, 13
`
`teDx talks, the New Startup economics:
`S t e p h e n F o r t e a t t e D x H K U S t ,
` youtube (Apr. 2, 2013) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .9
`
`timothy F. bresnahan, Jason p. David, and
`pai-ling yin, economic Value Creation
`in mobile Applications, Un I v e r S I t y o f
` chIcago preSS (July 2015) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .8
`
`Zack Whittaker, millions of steam game
`k e y s s t o l e n a f t e r h a c k e r b r e a c h e s
`gaming site, ZDNet (2016), . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .13
`
`
`
`Cited Authorities
`
`Page
`
`

`

`1
`
`inTeresT of Amicus curiAe1
`
`Act | the App Association (“App Association”)
`is an international grassroots advocacy and education
`organization representing more than 5,000 small app
`developers and technology firms in the digital economy.
`It is the only organization focused on the needs of small
`business innovators from around the world. the App
`Association advocates for an environment that inspires
`and rewards innovation while giving resources to help its
`members leverage their intellectual assets to raise capital,
`create jobs, and continue innovating.
`
`the App Association has participated as an amicus
`curiae in the Supreme court and other courts in cases
`related to antitrust and technological innovation. see,
`e.g., Petrella v. metro-Goldwyn-mayer, inc., 134 S. ct.
`1962 (2014); Dastar Corp. v. Twentieth Century Fox Film
`Corp., 539 U.S. 23 (2003); united states v. microsoft
`Corp., 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (en banc) (per curiam).
`technological innovation plays a critical role in enhancing
`competition and improving the welfare of consumers;
`therefore, the App Association has a keen interest in
`ensuring courts properly apply federal antitrust law to the
`dynamic industries and innovative technologies that drive
`the app ecosystem. the App Association’s members rely
`on app platforms give innovative products and services to
`
`1. Pursuant to Rule 37.6, amicus affirms that no counsel for
`a party authored this brief in whole or in part and that no person
`other than amicus and its counsel made a monetary contribution
`to its preparation or submission. both parties have consented to
`the filing of this brief.
`
`

`

`2
`
`billions of consumers in the United States and around the
`globe. If the Ninth circuit’s ruling stands, it will directly
`affect the viability of app platforms, as well as developers’
`ability to give services.
`
`summAry of ArgumenT
`
`Act | the App Association (“the App Association”)
`urges the court to overturn the Ninth circuit’s decision
`in this case on the basis that Respondent’s case relies on
`the misguided assumption that they are direct purchasers
`of petitioners. As an association that represents actual
`developers who rely on platforms such as the petitioner’s
`App Store, we find the Respondent’s characterization of
`the relationship between platforms and app developers to
`be factually inaccurate and disingenuously self-serving,
`especially their blatant disregard for how our members
`structure their pricing for their innovative products.
`
`Today, the app economy represents $568.47 billion of
`the United States’ economy and has 317,673 companies
`active in the U.S.’s mobile app market; the app economy
`is also responsible for creating 5,744,481 American jobs.
`the App Association has long believed that agency-sale
`relationships are procompetitive arrangements that
`lower costs for consumers and has contributed to the
`app economy’s success. the agency-sale approach gives
`independent app developers autonomy and flexibility in
`how they offer their apps to consumers, whether it be free
`with in-app purchases, subscription-based sales, one-time
`purchase, etc. see App Store guidelines. Successful app
`platforms, like petitioner’s App Store, have revolutionized
`the app ecosystem by providing app developers with
`eased access to a much broader swath of consumers and
`
`

`

`3
`
`platform users, resulting in a flourishing app economy that
`has enabled our members to grow and create 4.7 million
`American jobs. see Roya Stephens & Adarsh mahesh,
`state of the App economy, Act | the App Association
`(2018) Available at: http://actonline.org/wp-content/
`uploads/Act_2018-State-of-the-App-economy-Report_4.
`pdf. the App Association implores courts and lawmakers
`to avoid disrupting the symbiotic and pro-consumer
`relationship that exists between app developers and app
`platforms.
`
`In the instant case, the Ninth circuit completely
`ignored how our members interact with various mobile
`platforms by suggesting that petitioner owns and controls
`the relationship with our members’ customers. this
`implies that platforms serve more as resellers of apps it
`hosts on its platform and, thus, allows them to dictate the
`price of those apps to consumers. to assist this court,
`we explain and explore the realities of the relationship
`between app developers and app platforms. Additionally,
`we examine the net effects on American consumers; and
`why, ultimately, the Ninth circuit’s interpretation of this
`relationship, at the core of the matter at hand, is misguided
`and, if upheld, could damage and disrupt an ecosystem
`that has demonstrated significant societal value.
`
`moreover, the Ninth circuit’s interpretation of
`consumers as direct buyers from the petitioner incorrectly
`assumes the petitioner has ownership rights in app
`developers’ apps. to draw this conclusion, the Ninth
`circuit relies on its misunderstanding of the agency-sale
`relationship app developers have with platform owners.
`In reality, the petitioner is only entitled to the agreed
`upon percentage of the app developers’ app fee. Aside
`
`

`

`4
`
`from this fee, the petitioner has no ownership rights to
`the app. In addition, app developers can offer their apps
`on platforms not owned by the petitioner, unencumbered
`by the petitioner. All creative rights solely belong to the
`app developer and are uninhibited by the petitioner.
`moreover, when a consumer agrees to the “terms of
`service” for each app he or she buys, the app’s developer
`keeps sole responsibility for any breach of those terms.
`App developers are also solely responsible for any
`disruption in their service because of a lack of integrity
`in their code, and the onus is on them to fix it. Thus, the
`Ninth circuit appears to be confused as to what or from
`whom the consumer is buying when they purchase an app.
`by any estimation, it is clear that the consumer is the app
`developer’s customer, not the platform’s.
`
`the Ninth circuit also is indifferent as to who sets
`the prices of apps. Again, this point is undisputed from
`our perspective: the app developer sets this price. the
`petitioner is not making app developers set a price for the
`consumers who purchase their apps through the App Store
`platform, which is categorically inaccurate. moreover, this
`interpretation, in effect, misappropriates and confuses
`who pays for what in the app economy, which is precisely
`what illinois Brick sought to prevent from happening.
`
`At the heart of the illinois Brick doctrine, this
`court expressed concern of indirect purchasers taking
`issue with upstream negotiations and providing indirect
`purchasers the ability to object to the negotiated price
`from upstream agreements to which they were not a party.
`central in an illinois Brick analysis is examining where
`the direct contractual relationship exists; put another
`way: who is selling to whom. As a result, for purposes of
`
`

`

`5
`
`antitrust standing, people or entities can only sue those
`companies that have direct control over the product and
`its pricing.
`
`For these reasons, we respectfully request the court
`overturn the Ninth circuit’s decision in this case.
`
`ArgumenT
`
`i. The ninth Circuit factually ignoring the
`procompetitive Agency-sale relationship App
`Developers have with App stores fatally skews its
`reasoning and Conclusions
`
`the app ecosystem has developed alongside the rise of
`the smartphone and has experienced substantial growth
`in its less than ten years of existence. Small-to-medium
`entities (SMEs) are leaders in the $950.6 billion app
`ecosystem that has revolutionized the software industry
`and influenced every sector of the economy, representing
`approximately 4.7 million American jobs. Roya Stevens
`& Adarsh mahesh, state of the App economy, act |
`the app aSSocIatIon (2018) at http://actonline.org/wp-
`content/uploads/ Act_2018-State-of-the-App-economy-
`Report_4.pdf (App economy Report). to facilitate the
`rise of the internet of things (Iot)2, trusted and curated
`app stores will be vital to providing the apps that serve
`as the interface for Iot devices. the opportunities and
`potential for Iot will hinge on the app economy’s continued
`innovation, investment, and growth.
`
`2. Iot is an encompassing concept where everyday products
`use the internet to share data collected from sensors, enabling
`greater efficiency in processes, products, and services across
`every sector.
`
`

`

`6
`
`the App Association has long believed, and our
`experience for over a decade demonstrates, that agency-
`sale relationships are procompetitive arrangements that
`lower costs for consumers in the context of software apps.
`brief for Act | the App Association as Amicus curiae, p.
`11, Apple, inc, v. u.s., Case No. 15-565 (2015). The agency-
`sale approach gives independent app developers autonomy
`and flexibility in how they offer their apps to consumers,
`whether it be free with in-app purchases, subscription-
`based sales, one-time purchase, etc. see App Store
`guidelines. Successful app platforms, like petitioner’s App
`Store, have changed the app ecosystem, which provides
`app developers with ubiquitous access to a far broader
`swath of consumers and platform users worldwide than
`could be reached through the sole efforts of the developer.
`this scenario has led to a flourishing app economy
`that has benefited our members and consumers both.
`chuck Jones, Apple’s App store Generating meaningful
`Revenue, forBeS (Jan. 6, 2017, 2:10 PM), https://www.
`forbes.com/sites/chuckjones/2017/01/06/apples-app-
`store-generating-meaningful-revenue/#305d93011eb6
`(reporting developers receiving $20 billion in revenue).
`the App Association implores courts and lawmakers not
`to disrupt the symbiotic relationship existing between
`these two entities.
`
`In the instant case, the Ninth circuit completely
`ignored how our members interact with various mobile
`platforms by suggesting that petitioner owns and
`controls the relationship with our members’ customers.
`this implies platforms serve more as resellers of apps it
`hosts on its platform and, thus, allows them to dictate the
`price of those apps to consumers. to assist this court,
`we explain and explore the realities of the relationship
`between app developers and app platforms, and the net
`
`

`

`7
`
`effects on American consumers; and why, ultimately,
`the Ninth circuit’s interpretation of this relationship,
`at the core of the matter at hand, is misguided and, if
`upheld, could damage and disrupt an ecosystem that has
`demonstrated significant societal value.
`
`A. The benefits of the symbiotic relationship
`between app developers and app platforms
`
`the relationship between platforms and app companies
`is mutually beneficial, and one that should be fostered and
`supported. Not only do platforms provide app companies
`with secure market access, consumer trust, developer
`autonomy, dispute resolution, and meaningful consumer
`analytics; they provide a vital resource to bring the
`ingenuity and innovations of app companies to consumers
`around the globe. see App economy Report. Further,
`the developer-platform partnership is procompetitive
`and lowers costs for consumers. these relationships
`provide app developers with a significant amount of
`disintermediation to reach consumers around the globe
`without having the developer forfeit the ability to control
`their business and pricing structure. see Deloitte, The App
`economy of the united states: A Review of the mobile
`App market its Contribution to the united states, Report
`(forthcoming 2018) (finding that “app stores do not set the
`prices of apps, this decision being the sole prerogative of
`developers”) (Deloitte Study).
`
`1. platforms lower overhead costs that
`simplify market entry
`
`before centralized platforms, app developers were
`forced to absorb significant costs and manage various
`relationships to distribute their product to a wide
`
`

`

`8
`
`consumer base. see timothy F. bresnahan, Jason p.
`David, and pai-ling yin, economic Value Creation in
`mobile Applications, UniverSity Of ChiCagO preSS
`(July 2015). Available at http://www.nber.org/chapters/
`c13044.pdf (writing “[t]he rapid growth of mobile devices
`has been accompanied by an equally rapid growth in
`app development, in substantial part because platform
`providers Apple and google have lowered the costs of
`development and distribution of mobile applications.”).
`much more complex than a direct developer-consumer
`exchange, software companies used distributors to reach
`and engage with end users. Developers had to sacrifice
`valuable time from product development to establish
`relationships with distributors and were beholden to
`strict and costly rules even before they made their
`products available to consumers. today, the app economy
`represents $568.47 billion of the United States’ economy
`and has 317,673 companies active in the U.S.’s mobile app
`market; the app economy is also responsible for creating
`5,744,481 American jobs. see Deloitte Study.
`
`In simplest terms, independent software developers
`either paid to offload the overhead to a publisher or
`absorbed the cost and uncertainty of sales internally.
`these barriers to entry impacted hundreds of thousands
`of software developers and companies around the world;
`thus resulting in higher prices and fewer choices for
`consumers.
`
`While the concept of mobile platforms existed in both
`blackberry and Windowsce, it did not gather steam until
`2008, when petitioner paired its then-new iphone with
`an integrated application storefront. multiple companies
`quickly followed petitioner’s direction and launched stores
`
`

`

`9
`
`or marketplaces designed for various products. this
`created an entirely new internet-enabled economy that
`incorporated small businesses and reduced financial and
`temporal costs for developers.
`
`As we alluded to earlier, software companies incurred
`an extraordinary financial burden to bring their products
`to market before the introduction of mobile platforms. For
`instance, they had to engage in costly and time-consuming
`marketing campaigns to establish consumer trust and
`contract others to process financial transactions for them.
`Adam Jaffe & benjamin Jones, The Changing Frontier:
`Rethinking science and innovation Policy, National
`Bureau of Economic Research (2015) Available at https://
`books.google.com/books?id=QdopcwAAQbAJ&pg.
`platforms have since created a one-stop shop that
`mitigates these costs so that more small businesses, like
`our members, can take part in the app economy. see id.
`At p. 238 (2015) (writing “[t]he rapid emergence of many
`demanders, together with the very low barriers of entry
`created by the platform providers, has led to a rapid
`and very substantial expansion in the number of overall
`apps.”).
`
`In the late ‘90s, a software company had to spend
`about $10 million just to get up and running. see teDx
`talks, the New Startup economics: Stephen Forte
`at teDxHKUSt, youtube (Apr. 2, 2013), https://www.
`youtube.com/watch? v=t4IiyetJU_s.
`
`today, the advent of free or inexpensive cloud services,
`internet connectivity, and software tools have enabled
`small-business app developers to bring their innovative
`products to market with just a $100,000 check. see id.
`
`

`

`10
`
`platforms help lower the barrier to entry for small app
`companies by shouldering the costs of privacy measures,
`security, and intellectual property protections for their
`users, thereby freeing up substantial amounts of capital
`that startups can use to build and grow their business.
`
`With lower costs and barriers to entry, both fledgling
`and established app developers can succeed. For example,
`French educational app company l’escapadou secured
`1.3 million downloads and earned more than $1.5 million
`from app sales. Steve young, making $1.5 million with
`educational Apps with Pierre Abel, App masters (Apr. 30,
`2015) Available at: http://bit.ly/2hgDzZH. Founder pierre
`Abel specialized the language, content, and pricing of each
`of his apps based on consumers and market needs and
`marketed them on different platforms to reach a variety
`of consumers around the world. l’escapadou attributes
`its success to the centralized nature of platforms. see id.
`
`this lower overhead is why the app economy is highly
`competitive and one of the most innovative spaces on the
`internet-enabled ecosystem. see Deloitte Study (finding
`a causal relationship between app developers’ lowered
`overhead through the use of mobile platforms and the app
`economy’s success). For example, petitioner’s App Store
`provides a service that eases financial transactions (such as
`billing to consumers) and provides consumers assurances
`that all the apps sold are compliant with relevant tax
`codes—something that software developers had to handle
`themselves. popular platforms also may choose to absorb
`credit card fees to prevent them from transferring the cost
`to the developer. Without this platform-enabled service, it
`would fall on the app developer to handle each transaction;
`again, falling outside the bounds of an app developer’s
`
`

`

`11
`
`core competencies which, at times, is almost exclusively
`limited to writing the code for their app.
`
`2. platforms give app developers instant
`access to international markets
`
`Successful platforms, like petitioner’s App Store or
`google play, have changed the app ecosystem by providing
`app developers ubiquitous access to a broader swath of
`consumers. platforms provide a centralized framework for
`app developers to engage and secure visibility with the
`3.4 billion app users worldwide. Hugo Delgado, The App
`economy Forecast: A $6 Trillion market in the making,
`App Annie (2017) Available at: http://bit.ly/2xfDqtb.
`For instance, Petitioner’s App Store is available in 155
`countries around the globe. Ketan pratap, Apple says
`Developers earned Over $70 Billion since App store’s
`Launch, Gadget 360 (Jun. 1, 2017) http://gadgets.ndtv.com/
`apps/news/apple-says-app-store-earned-developers-70-
`billion-since-launch-1706781. by petitioner hosting an app
`company’s product on its platform, that app company now
`has immediate access and reach to the same markets as
`petitioner for a nominal fee without having to build a brick-
`and-mortar store or pay for an expensive an international
`ad campaign.
`
`3. Before platforms, app developers struggled
`to build trust with end users
`
`In the internet economy, end user trust – an established
`relationship between the app company and consumer
`where the consumer demonstrates confidence to disclose
`otherwise personal information to an app company – is
`extremely difficult to earn and maintain, especially
`
`

`

`12
`
`when a single incident (e.g., a breach or cyberattack) can
`permanently damage a business’s trust easily with their
`customer. However, for a small business app developer,
`this event can easily spell death for their company. While
`brick-and-mortar retailers may be able to operate without
`the use of most of a customer’s personal information, app
`companies need different types of personal information to
`develop and provide their innovative services to customers
`(e.g., geolocation data, financial information, health data).
`App companies are also different in that, without end
`user trust, consumers are unlikely to disclose essential
`information to an app company. therefore, consumer trust
`and willingness to share information are critical for an
`app developer to succeed in the market, more so than for
`brick-and-mortar.
`
`even before the advent of digital commerce, consumer
`trust was a critical aspect of a software developer’s ability
`to bring a product to market. erik brynjolfssn & michael
`Smith, Frictionless Commerce? A Comparison of internet
`and Conventional Retailers, MIT (1999) Available at:
`http://bit.ly/2yreJ8W (writing “[r]ecent scholars have
`argued that trust is among the most important components
`of any effective Internet marketing program.”). prior to
`platforms, software developers often had to hand over
`their products to companies with a significant reputation
`to break through the trust barrier. even “shareware”
`products that could be digitally distributed would end up
`partnering with trusted brands to gain consumer trust.
`Stew chyou, The History of shareware, thunderbolt (may
`5, 2011) Available at: http://bit.ly/2xvpuJ7. For example,
`in 1996, developers of the computer game ultimate Doom
`contracted with chex cereal to augment its consumer
`base. Developers converted their game software to create
`
`

`

`13
`
`the child-friendly game chex Quest. see id. today, most
`games, like ultimate Doom, are free to download on
`platforms in app form like petitioner’s App Store, google
`Play, or game-specific, independent platform Steam. These
`platforms not only lower cost but can reach consumers
`beyond those who buy a particular brand of cereal or
`trusted product. Now, platforms are the trusted product.
`
`but the trust mechanism provided by the platforms
`is not merely an aspect of size. consumer trust requires
`constant maintenance and vigilance because a loss of trust
`hurts platforms and the developers that depend on them.
`Zack Whittaker, millions of steam game keys stolen after
`hacker breaches gaming site, ZDNet (2016), Available at:
`http://zd.net/2bybRlV (reporting “[t]he data also includes
`an estimated 3.3 million unique site and forum accounts.”).
`the immediate consumer trust embedded into platforms’
`brands is worth billions of dollars. The economics Of
`Trust, Forbes (2010), Available at: http://bit.ly/2wJr76Y
`(writing “[t]he reason why the U.S. is richer than Somalia
`is mostly not because of culture. the great thing about
`formal systems, when well designed, is that they make a
`little bit of public spirit, altruism or professionalism go a
`long way,” says paul Seabright, an economics professor at
`the University of toulouse.”). platforms’ trusted brands
`allow developers to clear the critical hurdle of achieving
`trust from consumer adoption.
`
`4. platforms strengthen intellectual property
`protections for app developers
`
`In the age of retail software distribution, companies
`struggled to secure and protect their intellectual property
`from theft and copyright abuse. platforms not only
`
`

`

`14
`
`provide an important framework for app companies to
`engage with consumers, but they also assist in preventing
`infringement of app companies’ intellectual property.
`For example, petitioner’s platform provides a content
`dispute mechanism that allows app companies to submit a
`claim to connect with entities that have allegedly violated
`their intellectual property. Apple Inc., iTunes App store
`Content Dispute, Available at: http://apple.co/2xrvK9c.
`While maintaining a database of all the apps it hosts,
`the platform provides a mechanism that reduces the
`hurdles companies must go through to tackle copyright
`infringement. e.g., Dan Russell-pinson, OmG! someone
`Copied my App. What Do i Do Now?, act | the app
`aSSocIatIon (August 30, 2017) Available at: http://bit.
`ly/2wKvm23.
`
`Without the dispute resolution mechanisms of
`platforms, app companies are often left with an untenable
`alternative: copyright infringement litigation in federal
`court. Federal litigation poses an oppressive burden on
`app developers, particularly small businesses with limited
`resources. Within these cases, the rightful owners of the
`copyright may be faced with several thousand dollars per
`month in legal fees, the expense of new license compliance,
`and months or years diverted from company matters, not
`to mention the cost if the litigation is unsuccessful. Kelly
`Johnson Swan, united states: The True Cost of Defending
`Against Copyright infringement Litigation, Scott & Scott
`LLP (August 19, 2015) Available at: http://bit.ly/2xsdovf.
`platforms provide a vital, cost-effective avenue for app
`developers and copyright holders to dispute and address
`intellectual property theft and infringement.
`
`

`

`15
`
`B. By ignoring the roles of market participants
`in the App economy, the ninth Circuit’s
`functional Approach of the Direct sellers rule
`implicitly Categorizes petitioner as a reseller
`of all Apps it hosts on its platform
`
`the Ninth circuit’s decision at issue before this court
`radically expanded the eligible parties that may seek
`antitrust class action relief against digital commerce
`companies that utilize the agency sales approach by
`baselessly disregarding the fact that petitioner possesses
`no property right in an app developer’s product. Under
`Section 4 of the clayton Act, “any person who shall be
`injured in his business or property by reason of anything
`forbidden in the antitrust laws may sue…and shall recover
`threefold the damages by him sustained.” 15 U.S.C. § 15(a).
`by virtue of the clause “any person,” courts may apply the
`statute broadly. However, illinois Brick Co. v. illinois
`limited that definition by only permitting courts to grant
`antitrust standing under Rule 12(b)(6) if the plaintiff is
`the direct purchaser of the company that overcharged
`as opposed to “others in the chain of manufacture or
`distribution.” 431 U.S. 720, 729 (1977).
`
`In illinois Brick, the State of Illinois sued a concrete
`block manufacturer, Illinois Brick, for allegedly fixing
`prices of concrete blocks. the manufacturer had sold the
`blocks to masonry contractors who used the blocks to
`build structures. those contractors then subcontracted
`other companies to build those structures to later sell to
`the State of Illinois. the State then sued Illinois brick
`for passing on its unlawful overcharge at both stages
`of the distribution chain; thus, driving up the State’s
`
`

`

`16
`
`cost downstream when buying the structures from the
`contractors. In this case, this court rejected the State’s
`argument because, if it were to accept such an analysis,
`then it would make it almost impossible for a court to
`discern where the harm—in this case, an overcharged
`concrete block—actually occurred. Additionally, the
`policy behind this ruling was that holding indirect
`purchasers liable for passed-on overcharges would clog
`up the court sy

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket