`et al.,
`
`
`Plaintiffs,
`
`
`v.
`
`METROPOLITAN GOVERNMENT OF
`NASHVILLE AND DAVIDSON
`COUNTY,
`
`
`UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
`MIDDLE DISTRICT OF TENNESSEE
`NASHVILLE DIVISION
`
`)
`)
`)
`)
`)
`)
`)
`)
`)
`)
`)
`)
`
`
`
`
`
`
`No. 3:18-cv-00375
`
`
`
`
`Defendant.
`
`
`
`FINDINGS OF FACT AND CONCLUSIONS OF LAW
`
`This antitrust case concerns private security services in Davidson County, Tennessee. For
`
`years, private companies, including Plaintiffs, were the primary suppliers of private security
`
`services in Davidson County. Those private companies hired off-duty Metropolitan Nashville
`
`Police Department (“MNPD”) officers to provide part-time security services. Beginning in 2013,
`
`MNPD started a five-year plan to transition the secondary employment of off-duty MNPD officers
`
`away from private companies. As MNPD implemented this transition, it also decided to enter the
`
`private security services market. In order to win business, MNPD lowered rates, changed
`
`administrative procedures, and eventually prohibited off-duty MNPD officers from working for
`
`private security companies. MNPD won a number of contracts previously held by private security
`
`companies and became a significant player in the private security services market.
`
`Plaintiffs allege a disruption caused by MNPD’s aggressive, competitive, and successful
`
`entry into the private security services market. They argue that MNPD was successful through the
`
`use of anticompetitive conduct in violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 2
`
`Case 3:18-cv-00375 Document 147 Filed 06/09/21 Page 1 of 17 PageID #: 2122
`
`
`
`(“Section 2”).1 A bench trial was held on November 12 through 16, 2020, (Doc. Nos. 138-140),
`
`and the parties submitted post-trial briefs. (Doc. No. 137, 145, 146). The Court makes the
`
`following Findings of Fact and Conclusions of Law in accordance with Rule 52(a) of the Federal
`
`Rules of Civil Procedure.
`
`FINDINGS OF FACT
`
`The Private Security Services Market In Davidson County, Tennessee
`
`1.
`
`Plaintiffs are three long-established private security companies operating in
`
`Davidson County, Tennessee. Comprehensive Security, Inc. (“Comprehensive”) is headed by
`
`Loyd Poteete, a former MNPD officer. Associated Protected Services (“APS”) is owned by
`
`Michael Woods, a former Millersville, Tennessee police officer. OnTrac Security is operated by
`
`Ralph Douglas Jones, a formed MNPD sergeant.
`
`2.
`
`Plaintiffs offer traditional police and security services to the public, including site
`
`security, asset security, traffic control, crowd control, individual protection and other similar
`
`security services.
`
`3.
`
`In order to deliver police and other security services, Plaintiffs hire off-duty police
`
`officers as part-time employees on an as-needed basis. (Doc. No. 138 at 16-26, 157-60). Those
`
`off-duty officers are either commissioned by the Tennessee Peace Officer Standards & Training
`
`Commission (“POST officers”) or without a POST commission. (Id. at 17-19, 26, 159-63, 191).
`
`The distinction is significant because only POST officers can make arrests and direct traffic on
`
`public streets. (Id. at 16; Doc. No. 139 at 26; Doc. No. 140 at 66). Most of the off-duty officers
`
`typically work full-time for local and state governmental law enforcement agencies, such as
`
`MNPD, and receive employment benefits and annual training through that employment. As a
`
`
`1 Plaintiffs abandoned their Section 2 predatory pricing claim. (Doc. No. 145 at 2, 32).
`
`
`Case 3:18-cv-00375 Document 147 Filed 06/09/21 Page 2 of 17 PageID #: 2123
`
`2
`
`
`
`
`
`result, private security companies benefit greatly from having access to trained off-duty officers
`
`who desire sporadic, additional part-time work pay without incurring the training cost or other
`
`costs associated with regular employees. (Doc. No. 139 at 116). Having this ready labor made it
`
`easier for private security companies, like Plaintiffs, to fulfill their contractual security obligations
`
`in Davidson County. (Doc. No. 138 at 171-72).
`
`4.
`
`MNPD facilitated the success of private security companies through secondary
`
`employment policies and procedures. As far back as the 1990s, an MNPD officer who wanted to
`
`work part-time for a private security company could submit a secondary employment work
`
`request, known as a Form 150, and approval was “pretty much guaranteed.” (Doc. No. 138 at 173;
`
`see also id. 51-52; Doc. No. 119-20). In 1997, MNPD created the Secondary Employment Unit
`
`(“SEU”), to help MNPD officers obtain approval of secondary employment requests. The SEU
`
`gave private security companies “very easy” access to a “great pool” of MNPD officers that were
`
`“on standby constantly.” (Doc. No. 138 at 51-53, 172).
`
`5.
`
`The cooperative relationship between MNPD and private security companies
`
`extended to Metro’s Special Events Committee, which consisted of representatives from the
`
`Mayor’s Office, Public Works, Metro Parks, MNPD, Metro Fire, and special event coordinators.
`
`The Committee’s responsibilities included the planning, permitting, and approval of special events
`
`in Davidson County. (Id. at 37-38, 175; Doc. No. 139 at 57-58). The inclusion of Plaintiffs and
`
`other private security companies reflected the then market reality that private security companies
`
`did the “lion’s share of [the private security] work,” and were able to share their expertise on
`
`security, road closures, and traffic control. (Doc. No. 139 at 58-59).
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`3
`
`Case 3:18-cv-00375 Document 147 Filed 06/09/21 Page 3 of 17 PageID #: 2124
`
`
`
`Chief Anderson’s Five-Year Transition Plan for MNPD
`
`6.
`
`In April 2013, then MNPD Chief Steve Anderson announced a five-year transition
`
`plan to change “the future of secondary employment of [MNPD] police officers” and to ensure the
`
`“safety” of citizens and visitors. (Ex. 68 at 2, 6). In an April 26, 2013 email to city officials, Chief
`
`Anderson explained that “practices relating to the off-duty employment of police officers that were
`
`in place 20 years ago would not be acceptable today.” (Id. at 2). He explained that there was “little
`
`or no regulation or oversight as to how, or even where, officers used their police authority in off-
`
`duty employment,” and that without “sufficient oversight, there is the real potential, and as we
`
`have seen in other cities, [for] the reality of inappropriate conduct, favoritism, misbehavior and/or
`
`corruption.” (Id.) He was committed to “improving accountability and reducing liability to the
`
`city” by changing the availability and controls surrounding secondary employment of off-duty
`
`MNPD officers. (Id.)
`
`7.
`
`Chief Anderson also determined that continued employment of MNPD officers by
`
`private security companies had “the potential to divide an [MNPD] officer’s loyalties, create
`
`conflicts of interest and otherwise have a detrimental effect on the operation of the Metropolitan
`
`Government.” (Id. at 3). So, he decided to restrict officers’ secondary employment by requiring
`
`that all private security services work be approved by MNPD. (Id.) This would enable MNPD to
`
`“limit its liability and exercise sufficient control so as to minimize any detrimental impact
`
`[secondary employment] can create.” (Id.) The change would also help MNPD become more
`
`“professional [and] coordinated,” and “enhance public safety and service.” (Id. at 6).
`
`8.
`
`The transition plan for MNPD officers’ secondary employment would occur over
`
`five years to avoid any “outcry” over sudden change to an existing system “[e]ngrained into the
`
`culture of Nashville.” (Id.) It was important to Chief Anderson that special event planners would
`
`Case 3:18-cv-00375 Document 147 Filed 06/09/21 Page 4 of 17 PageID #: 2125
`
`4
`
`
`
`
`
`not hire MNPD officers directly unless the fees charged by MNPD were “reasonable and
`
`affordable.” (Id. at 5). He explained that it was “imperative” that MNPD “give the Nashville
`
`community and event organizers an affordable way to have Metropolitan Nashville police officers
`
`staff their events.” (Id. at 5-6).
`
`9.
`
`MNPD Captain David Corman, the head of SEU from 2010 to 2019, was
`
`responsible for implement Chief Anderson’s five-year transition plan. (Doc. No. 140 at 76).
`
`10.
`
`Beginning in April 2013, Corman began the process. First, the focus of SEU
`
`changed to obtaining private security contracts for MNPD that could be directly staffed with
`
`MNPD officers. (Doc. No. 139 at 37). MNPD Sergeant Kim Forsyth testified that Corman was
`
`concerned that private security companies were using MNPD’s officers to make their own money,
`
`and he became excited at the prospect of generating business for MNPD. (Id. at 37-38). Forsyth, a
`
`witness offered by Plaintiffs, was very critical and accusatory of Corman. She believed that
`
`Corman wanted to make as much money as possible for MNPD and operated SEU with the goal
`
`of eliminating the work available to private security companies so that eventually they would be
`
`forced out of business. At trial, she was nervous, unsure, fearful and contrived. She lacked any
`
`direct or indirect knowledge about MNPD’s anti-competitive activities or motive. Instead, her
`
`testimony consisted of aggressive, prepackaged speeches that were often not responsive to
`
`questions. Overall, the Court found Forsyth not credible, and likely influenced by personal feelings
`
`about Corman.
`
`11.
`
`Second, Corman implemented administrative changes to add “more structure” and
`
`“more oversight” to the Form 150 process for approving secondary requests. (Doc. No. 140; see
`
`also Doc. No. 138 at 51-57, 173-75). For example, MNPD required multiple escalating levels of
`
`approval – first by the captain or precinct commander, then by the head of SEU, and eventually by
`
`Case 3:18-cv-00375 Document 147 Filed 06/09/21 Page 5 of 17 PageID #: 2126
`
`5
`
`
`
`
`
`Chief Anderson. (Doc. No. 54-55, 173). MNPD also made a determination on each private security
`
`work opportunity to access whether it was “worthwhile.” (Id. at 173-74). As a result, it became
`
`more difficult to get Form 150 approvals, and private security companies began to rely more on
`
`non-MNPD officers. (Id. at 78-80, 87-90).
`
`12.
`
`Third, the five-year transition plan also changed the operation of the Special Events
`
`Committee. No longer were private security companies, like Plaintiffs, invited by Metro to attend
`
`meetings. Instead, they had to be invited by special event planners to discuss individual projects.
`
`(Id. at 69-70, 195-97; Doc. No. 140 at 140-41). The most significant change occurred when MNPD
`
`began promoting itself to special event planners to provide private security services for their
`
`events. (Doc. No. 138 at 176, 196; Doc. No. 139 at 71-72). As Michael Woods of Plaintiff APS
`
`conceded, MNPD was merely “let[ting] [event organizers] know they had other options.” (Doc.
`
`No. 138 at 198).
`
`13.
`
`Between 2013 and 2018, Plaintiffs, and other private security companies, felt the
`
`impact of MNPD entrance into the private security market. In their case-in-chief, Plaintiffs painted
`
`an impressive picture through multiple private security companies who told stories of losing
`
`business to MNPD. According to them, MNPD used the Special Events Committee, control over
`
`the availability of off-duty MNPD offers through the Form 150 process, the parade permit process
`
`and the approval process for road closure to systemically take business that previously went to
`
`Plaintiffs and other private security companies. A few examples illustrate MNPD’s takeover of the
`
`customer base for the private security market:
`
`• For many years, Patrick McKellar and his company provided security for the annual
`
`Iroquois Steeplechase event, until he lost that work to MNPD.
`
`Case 3:18-cv-00375 Document 147 Filed 06/09/21 Page 6 of 17 PageID #: 2127
`
`6
`
`
`
`
`
`• George H. Curry, Jr. provided security services for all events at the Ryman
`
`Auditorium and the Grand Ole Opry House until he lost that work to Ryman’s in-
`
`house security force in 2018 because he could no longer employ MNPD officers.
`
`• Doug Jones provided security services for TriStar Hospitals, which are part of the
`
`HCA family of companies. His contract approached 1 million dollars and was lost
`
`to MNPD in 2018.
`
`• Also in 2018, Chaz Vetter, owner of Premier Protective Services, Inc., provided
`
`security services to the State Fairgrounds for at least six years until he lost that work
`
`to MNPD.
`
`• Comprehensive, owned by Loyd Poteete, lost its customer, the Nashville Pride
`
`Festival to MNPD, which provided security services for free.
`
`• APS, owned by Michael Woods, lost work for the Nashville Pride Festival and the
`
`Nashville Christmas Parade to MNPD.
`
`Completion of the Five-Year Transition Plan
`
`14.
`
`On March 2, 2018 – almost exactly five years after announcing the five-year
`
`transition plan – Chief Anderson issued a memorandum ending MNPD’s approval of MNPD
`
`officers’ requests to perform off-duty work for private security companies. (Ex. 6; Doc. No. 138
`
`at 60-61; Doc. No. 139 at 14). This effectively ended Plaintiffs’ ability to hire off-duty MNPD
`
`officers to staff their private security services contracts. Now, Plaintiffs had to use non-MNPD
`
`officers. (Doc. No. 138 at 90-94).
`
`15.
`
`As a result, SEU now “operate[s] the same way” as a private security company and
`
`“provide[s] businesses or individuals an opportunity to hire [MNPD] police officers” for private
`
`security services. (Doc. No. 140 at 36, 113). SEU has been very successful. (Doc. No. 139 at 47,
`
`Case 3:18-cv-00375 Document 147 Filed 06/09/21 Page 7 of 17 PageID #: 2128
`
`7
`
`
`
`
`
`49, 81-82). MNPD has obtained a number of significant contracts previously held by Plaintiffs and
`
`other private security companies. In some cases, MNPD even offered free or discounted private
`
`security services to the public. (Doc. No. 138 at 28-32; 178-80).
`
`16. MNPD rates for private security services reflects its entrance into, and competition
`
`within, the private security market. From 2009 until 2013, Metro’s range for hourly services
`
`ranged from $66.00 per hour to $116.00 per hour, much higher than the private security companies.
`
`Ex. 61 at 1. But in 2013, when MNPD began to implement Chief Anderson’s five-year transition
`
`plan, MNPD lowered the range to $40.00 per hour to $75.00 per hour. (Id.) There was a small
`
`increase in 2017 to a range of $44.50 per hour to $79.50 per hour, encompassing completion of
`
`the five-year plan in 2018. (Id. at 2.) Finally, in 2020 to 2021, after MNPD had obtained many of
`
`Plaintiffs’ and other private security companies’ clients, the range had a modest increase to $46.50
`
`per hour to $79.50 per hour. (Id.)
`
`Expert Opinions
`
`17.
`
`At trial, the Court qualified two witnesses as experts under Federal Rule of
`
`Evidence 702: Dr. Gilbert Mathis, Professor Emeritus of Economics at Murray State University,
`
`on behalf of Plaintiffs (Ex. 40), Dr. Charles L. Baum II, Professor of Economics at Middle
`
`Tennessee State University, a rebuttal expert on behalf of Defendant. (Ex. 60). Having considered
`
`the testimony of both, the Court gives little weight to Dr. Mathis’s opinions because the Court
`
`finds them to be flawed due to incomplete analysis.
`
`18.
`
`Dr. Mathis opined that MNPD was anticompetitive when it reduced the available
`
`labor pool needed by Plaintiffs and other private security companies to compete in the private
`
`security services market. According to Dr. Mathis, MNPD increased market power and decreased
`
`competition when it restricted off-duty MNPD officers from working for Plaintiffs.
`
`Case 3:18-cv-00375 Document 147 Filed 06/09/21 Page 8 of 17 PageID #: 2129
`
`8
`
`
`
`
`
`19.
`
`The Court concludes that Dr. Mathis’s opinion is unreliable. (Doc. No. 139 at 136-
`
`47, 176-79). First, Dr. Mathis analyzed the wrong market. As credibly explained by Dr. Baum, Dr.
`
`Mathis failed to analyze the sell-side market for the supply of private security services that is the
`
`basis of Plaintiffs’ claim. (Doc. No. 139 at 152). Indeed, contrary to Plaintiffs’ own legal
`
`arguments, Dr. Mathis insisted that this case concerns buyers, not sellers. (Doc. No. 138 at 120-
`
`21). Dr. Mathis compounded this error by rejecting, contrary to the evidence at trial, that the
`
`“buyers” relevant to private security services are special event planners and organizers. Instead,
`
`Dr. Mathis devised a market in which the buyers are private security companies and the product is
`
`off-duty officers employed by law enforcement agencies. (Id. at 112, 121-22; Ex. 40 at 1-3).
`
`Because his “labor pool” market focus bears no resemblance to the private security service supply
`
`market at issue in this case, Dr. Baum concluded that Dr. Mathis failed to demonstrate that MNPD
`
`had market power. (Doc. No. 139 at 133, 137-38). The Court agrees that the labor pool market
`
`analysis offers little insight into MNPD’s alleged anticompetitive behavior in the supply-side
`
`security service market.
`
`20.
`
`Even if the labor pool market analysis were relevant, Dr. Mathis used untenable
`
`assumptions that undercut his conclusions. In particular, Dr. Mathis did not include all available
`
`off-duty officers such as non-POST officers, retired POST officers, Tennessee Highway Patrol
`
`officers, and officers in nearby counties. (Id. at 136-47, 190-91). His contrary assumptions are
`
`wholly unsupported by the evidence at trial. Rather, the evidence at trial establishes that private
`
`security companies routinely hire non-POST officers, retired POST officers, THP officers, and
`
`POST officers from law enforcement agencies in geographically distant counties, including as far
`
`as Alabama. (Doc. No. 138 at 17-22, 26, 58, 87, 90-91, 163, 191; Doc. No. 139 at 100; Doc. No.
`
`140 at 144). Moreover, Dr. Mathis acknowledged making no attempt to ascertain how many
`
`Case 3:18-cv-00375 Document 147 Filed 06/09/21 Page 9 of 17 PageID #: 2130
`
`9
`
`
`
`
`
`MNPD officers are willing or able to work for private security companies. (Doc. No. 138 at 127-
`
`29). Indeed, Dr. Mathis conceded at trial that he did not consider much of the available information
`
`about private security companies’ labor force; that it was reasonable to consider such data; and
`
`that correcting his assumptions with such data would alter his conclusions. (Id. at 114; 118-20;
`
`125-30).
`
`21.
`
`The HHI value calculated by Dr. Mathis is also unreliable. The HHI, typically used
`
`to evaluate a market in a merger case, has more limited utility in a Section 2 case concerned with
`
`the market power of a single firm. Moreover, Dr. Mathis’s method for calculating the HHI value
`
`likely overstated the results. Again, as Dr. Baum credibly explained, Dr. Mathis considered all of
`
`the POST officers in five counties as one “unit,” instead of following standard principles and
`
`squaring the shares of the employers that supply POST officers in each county. (Doc. No. 139 at
`
`176-83). “[L]umping all the firms in a county together and consider[ing] that to be one entity”
`
`makes the labor pool “seem way more concentrated than it really is.” (Id.)
`
`22.
`
`Finally, Dr. Mathis assumes that the “reasonable available” labor pool for private
`
`security companies includes MNPD, but he concedes that MNPD is not obligated to make its
`
`officers available to private security companies at all. (Doc. No. 138 at 136-37). In rebuttal, Dr.
`
`Baum stressed that Dr. Mathis failed to acknowledge that “there is no economic theory . . . that
`
`says it’s somehow anticompetitive for a company to not allow its workers to work for another
`
`company.” (Doc. No. 139 at 135-36). Dr. Mathis compounded this error by failing to ever consider
`
`the stated purposes for Chief Anderson’s MNPD secondary employment transition plan. (Doc. No.
`
`138 at 140). As a result, the labor pool market analysis entirely fails to take into account MNPD’s
`
`alternate reasons for limiting the outside work of its officers, including “provid[ing] better security
`
`and control[ling] MNPD’s public image.” (Doc. No. 139 at 168, 187).
`
`Case 3:18-cv-00375 Document 147 Filed 06/09/21 Page 10 of 17 PageID #: 2131
`
`10
`
`
`
`
`
`CONCLUSIONS OF LAW
`
`Antitrust Law and the Sherman Act
`
`1.
`
`The antitrust laws protect “competition, not competitors.” Brown Shoe Co. v.
`
`United States, 370 U.S. 294, 320 (1962). To violate the Sherman Act, a firm must engage in
`
`anticompetitive conduct “designed to destroy competition, not just to eliminate a competitor.”
`
`Richter Concrete Corp. v. Hilltop Concrete Corp., 691 F.2d 818, 823 (6th Cir. 1982). Congress
`
`authorized Sherman Act scrutiny of a single firm only when the firm poses a danger of
`
`monopolization. This strict focus “reduces the risk that the antitrust laws will dampen the
`
`competitive zeal of a single aggressive entrepreneur.” Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube
`
`Corp., 467 U.S. 752, 768 (1984). Section 2 thus prohibits only monopolizing, attempting to
`
`monopolize, or conspiring with others to monopolize, commerce.2 15 U.S.C. § 2; Superior Prod.
`
`P’ship v. Gordon Auto Body Parts Co., 784 F.3d 311, 318 (6th Cir. 2015).
`
`2.
`
`To prove monopolization, a plaintiff must prove that a firm: (1) “possess[ed]
`
`monopoly power in a relevant market”; (2) “willful[ly] acqui[red], maint[ained], or use[d] [ ] that
`
`power by anti-competitive or exclusionary means as opposed to ‘growth or development resulting
`
`from a superior product, business acumen, or historic accident,’” Conwood Co. v. U.S. Tobacco
`
`Co., 290 F.3d 768, 782 (6th Cir. 2002) (quoting Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing
`
`Corp., 472 U.S. 585, 595-96 (1985)); and (3) had a general intent to exclude others from the
`
`market. Superior Prod. P’ship, 784 F.3d at 319 (quoting Conwood, 290 F.3d at 782).
`
`
`2 The Clayton Act provides the vehicle to sue for redress under Section 2. Section 16 of the Clayton
`Act provides in part that “[a]ny person, firm, corporation, or association shall be entitled to sue for
`and have injunctive relief . . . against threatened loss or damage by a violation of the antitrust
`laws[.]” 15 U.S.C. § 26.
`
`
`Case 3:18-cv-00375 Document 147 Filed 06/09/21 Page 11 of 17 PageID #: 2132
`
`11
`
`
`
`
`
`3.
`
`To prove attempted monopolization, a plaintiff must prove that a firm: (1) “with a
`
`dangerous probability of success, engage[d] in anti-competitive practices the specific design of
`
`which [was] to build a monopoly or exclude or destroy competition”; and (2) had a “specific intent
`
`to destroy competition or build a monopoly.”3 Conwood, 290 F.3d at 782 (quoting Smith v. N.
`
`Mich. Hosps., Inc., 703 F.2d 942, 954 (6th Cir. 1983)); Superior Prod. P’ship, 784 F.3d at 319;
`
`Arthur S. Langenderfer, Inc. v. S.E. Johnson Co., 917 F.2d 1413, 1431-32 (6th Cir. 1990). To
`
`satisfy the “dangerous probability of success” element, a firm must demonstrably “possess market
`
`strength that approaches monopoly power.” Langenderfer, 917 F.2d at 1431-32; Tarrant Serv.
`
`Agency, Inc. v. Am. Standard, Inc., 12 F.3d 609, 615 (6th Cir. 1993).
`
`4.
`
`Consideration of every Section 2 claim begins with two threshold issues: (1) the
`
`definition of “the relevant product and geographic markets” in which the plaintiffs compete with
`
`the defendant, and (2) whether the defendant, “in fact, possesses monopoly power.” Spirit Airlines,
`
`Inc. v. Northwest Airlines, Inc., 431 F.3d 917, 932 (6th Cir. 2005) (quoting Conwood, 290 F.3d at
`
`782); see also United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 395 (1956); Hand v.
`
`Cent. Transp., Inc., 779 F.2d 8, 11 (6th Cir. 1985).
`
`5.
`
`The proof at trial established, by a preponderance of the evidence, that Plaintiffs
`
`and other private security companies primarily used full-time MNPD officers and other law
`
`enforcement officers to supply the labor necessary to staff their for-profit companies providing
`
`security services to the public. They relied greatly upon MNPD. Their business model worked well
`
`because MNPD hired, trained, paid, and controlled their labor source with no direct costs to
`
`
`3 Specific intent may be inferred from evidence of anticompetitive conduct, Langenderfer, 917
`F.2d at 1432, and courts have found “[i]mproper exclusion . . . is always deliberately intended.”
`Spirit Airlines v. NW Airlines, Inc., 431 F.3d 917, 932 (6th Cir. 2005)(citing Aspen Skiing, 472
`U.S. at 603).
`
`Case 3:18-cv-00375 Document 147 Filed 06/09/21 Page 12 of 17 PageID #: 2133
`
`12
`
`
`
`
`
`Plaintiffs. Then, in 2013, MNPD changed its administration of its employees. MNPD decided that
`
`more management and control was needed to maintain MNPD standards when its employees
`
`engaged in off-duty secondary employment. Recognizing that some MNPD officers wanted and
`
`needed part-time work for additional pay, MNPD entered the private security services market
`
`using its employees. Plaintiffs’ claims that MNPD’s decision to compete with Plaintiffs is a
`
`violation of the antitrust laws is fundamentally flawed. Nothing in Section 2 of the Sherman Act
`
`requires MNPD to make its employees available to a for-profit company. Nothing in Section 2 of
`
`the Sherman Act requires MNPD to refrain from competing against Plaintiffs in the private
`
`security market. Nothing in Section 2 of the Sherman Act makes illegal MNPD decision to
`
`compete against Plaintiff. And, certainly nothing in Section 2 of the Sherman Act requires MNPD
`
`to help its competition once MNPD enters the market. For the reasons that follow, there is no
`
`violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act in this case.
`
`Market Definition
`
`6.
`
`Plaintiffs must first accurately define the relevant market in which they compete
`
`with MNPD. Worldwide Basketball & Sport Tours, Inc. v. Nat’l Collegiate Athletic Ass’n, 388
`
`F.3d 955, 962 (6th Cir. 2004); see also In re Se. Milk Antitrust Litig., 801 F. Supp. 2d 705, 724
`
`(E.D. Tenn. 2011). The relevant market consists of two components: (1) product or service market,
`
`and (2) geographic market. Brown Shoe, 370 U.S. at 324; Spirit Airlines, 431 F.3d at 932-33; In
`
`re Se. Milk, 801 F. Supp. 2d at 724. Here, by a preponderance of the evidence, it is apparent that
`
`Plaintiffs, MNPD, and other private security companies compete primarily in the Nashville,
`
`Davidson County, Tennessee market in the private security market.
`
`7.
`
`Plaintiffs contend that the appropriate service market is the supply of private
`
`security services “that require POST-commissioned officers.” (Doc. No. 132 at 2; Doc. No. 145 at
`
`Case 3:18-cv-00375 Document 147 Filed 06/09/21 Page 13 of 17 PageID #: 2134
`
`13
`
`
`
`
`
`¶ 206). However, Plaintiffs have not proven this narrow definition by a preponderance of the
`
`evidence. First, Plaintiffs have offered no antitrust analysis to support the definition. Dr. Mathis
`
`disagreed with the definition entirely and offered no relevant analysis of any supply market. And
`
`Plaintiffs presented no qualitative information to support the definition (e.g., data regarding the
`
`number and size of market participants; specific services supplied in the market; cross-elasticity;
`
`firms that have left the market; firms that could enter the market; barriers to entry, etc.) Indeed,
`
`Dr. Baum credibly opined that Plaintiffs did not even collect the appropriate data to analyze the
`
`supply market. (Doc. No. 139 at 139, 152).
`
`Monopoly Power
`
`8.
`
`The Court next considers the “critical factor” of whether MNPD has monopoly
`
`power in the relevant market. Byars v. Bluff City News Co., 609 F.2d 843, 850 (6th Cir. 1979)
`
`(citing American Tobacco Co. v. United States, 328 U.S. 781, 813-14 (1946)). A single seller has
`
`monopoly power when it is able to raise prices or exclude competition when it desires to do so.
`
`Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Tech. Servs., 504 U.S. 451, 464 (1992) (quoting Fortner Enters., Inc.
`
`v. U.S. Steel Corp., 394 U.S. 495, 503 (1969)); see also E.I. du Pont, 351 U.S. at 391.
`
`9.
`
`“The existence of [monopoly] power ordinarily is inferred from the seller’s
`
`possession of a predominant share of the [relevant] market.” Spirit Airlines, 431 F.3d at 935
`
`(quoting Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 464). Although Section 2 does not contain a specific
`
`percentage of market share that triggers an inference of monopoly power, courts have adopted a
`
`standard that is “very high.” In re Se. Milk, 801 F. Supp. 2d at 725 (citing Smith Wholesale Co.,
`
`Inc. v. Philip Morris USA, Inc., 219 F. App’x 398, 409 (6th Cir. 2007)). In particular, the Sixth
`
`Circuit typically infers monopoly power “where the market share is 75-80% or greater.” Byars,
`
`609 F.2d at 850 (emphasis added). The Sixth Circuit has also endorsed Judge Learned Hand’s
`
`Case 3:18-cv-00375 Document 147 Filed 06/09/21 Page 14 of 17 PageID #: 2135
`
`14
`
`
`
`
`
`“classic explanation” of market share sufficient to constitute monopoly power: “over ninety . . .
`
`percentage [market share] is enough to constitute a monopoly; it is doubtful whether sixty or sixty-
`
`four percent would be enough; and certainly thirty-three percent is not.” Spirit Airlines, 431 F.3d
`
`at 935 (emphasis added) (quoting United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 148 F.2d 416, 424
`
`(2d Cir. 1945)).
`
`10.
`
`The Sixth Circuit has also taken a demanding approach to whether a plaintiff has
`
`demonstrated market share “approach[ing] monopoly power” sufficient to satisfy the “dangerous
`
`probability of success” element of an attempted monopolization claim. Langenderfer, 917 F.2d at
`
`1431-32; Tarrant, 12 F.3d at 615. Twice, the court has held that a market share between 30 and 40
`
`percent was insufficient evidence that a firm had even the capacity to monopolize. See Richter,
`
`691 F.2d at 826; Langenderfer, 917 F.2d at 1431.
`
`11.
`
`Plaintiffs have not established MNPD’s market share. As discussed above, Dr.
`
`Mathis conducted a “buy-side” study of a “reasonable labor pool” that offers no insight into
`
`MNPD’s share of the relevant sell-side market. Moreover, even if Dr. Mathis’s labor pool analysis
`
`were relevant and reliable, it is insufficient to demonstrate monopoly power because MNPD’s
`
`“share” is below the high threshold required under Section 2. Byars, 609 F.2d at 850. Indeed, Dr.
`
`Mathis implicitly acknowledged this shortfall by concluding that MNPD has only “considerable
`
`market power,” not monopoly power. (See Ex. 40 at 3-4). Finally, Plaintiffs’ anecdotal evidence
`
`at trial concerning MNPD’s performance in the relevant market does not alone support a finding,
`
`of monopoly power. Accordingly, Plaintiffs have failed to prove, by a preponderance of the
`
`evidence, that MNPD possesses sufficient market share for the Court to infer the existence of
`
`monopoly power in the relevant market.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`15
`
`Case 3:18-cv-00375 Document 147 Filed 06/09/21 Page 15 of 17 PageID #: 2136
`
`
`
`Anticompetitive Conduct
`
`12.
`
`Even if Plaintiffs had met their burden regarding monopoly power in the relevant
`
`market, their Section 2 claims still fail because Plaintiffs have not proven that MNPD engaged in
`
`anticompetitive conduct. There is insufficient proof that MNPD “willful[ly] acqui[red],
`
`maint[ained], or use[d] [monopoly] power by anti-competitive or exclusionary means as opposed
`
`to ‘growth or development resulting from a superior product, business acumen, or historic
`
`accident,’” or “engage[d] in anti-competitive practices the specific design of which [was] to build
`
`a monopoly or exclude or destroy competition.” Conwood, 290 F.3d at 782 (quoting Aspen Skiing,
`
`472 U.S. at 595-96 and Smith, 703 F.2d at 954); see also Superior Prod. P’ship, 784 F.3d at 319.
`
`Neither have Plaintiffs proved that MNPD engaged in other anticompetitive behavior designed to
`
`destroy competition. See Richter, 691 F.2d at 823 (explaining that anticompetitive conduct is
`
`“designed to destroy competition, not just to eliminate a competitor”).
`
`13.
`
`This Court does not find that Chief Anderson’s five-year transition plan was
`
`intended to “destroy competition.” His plan was largely inward-looking and concerned MNPD and
`
`MNPD officers. (See Ex. 68). Chief Anderson outlined specific and credible business reasons and
`
`police powers for the transition plan, including that MNPD sought better control over its own
`
`officers; better management of its reputation; limitation of complaints; improved training and risk
`
`management; and a better ability to provide for the public safety. Likewise, Plaintiffs offered
`
`insufficient evidence that changes to the Special Events Committee meetings were intended to
`
`“destroy competition.” In shor