throbber

`
`20–1766
`In re American Express Anti-Steering Rules Antitrust Litigation
`In the
`United States Court of Appeals
`FOR THE SECOND CIRCUIT
`
`
`AUGUST TERM 2020
`No. 20-1766
`
`IN RE AMERICAN EXPRESS ANTI-STEERING RULES ANTITRUST
`LITIGATION,
`
`
`LAJOLLA AUTO TECH, INC., QWIK LUBE LLC,
`Plaintiffs-Appellants,
`
`RITE AID CORPORATION, WALGREEN CO., FIREFLY AIR SOLUTIONS,
`LLC, PLYMOUTH OIL CORPORATION, RITE AID HEADQUARTERS
`CORP., JASA, INC., ON BEHALF OF THEMSELVES AND ALL SIMILARLY
`SITUATED PERSONS, ANIMAL LAND, INC., ROOKIES, INC., ITALIAN
`COLORS RESTAURANT, COHEN RESE GALLERY, INC., LOPEZ-DEJONGE,
`INC., BAR HAMA LLC, MEIJER, INC., PUBLIX SUPER MARKET, INC.,
`RALEY’S, SUPERVALU INC., CVS PHARMACY, INC., BI-LO, LLC, H.E.B.
`GROCERY COMPANY, THE KROGER CO., SAFEWAY INC., AHOLD
`U.S.A. INC., ALBERTSON’S LLC, HY-VEE, INC., THE GREAT ATLANTIC
`& PACIFIC TEA COMPANY INC., TREEHOUSE, INC., IL FORNO, INC.,
`NATIONAL SUPERMARKETS ASSOCIATION, INC., ON BEHALF OF ITS
`MEMBERSHIP, AND ALL OTHER SIMILARLY SITUATED PERSONS,
`PLAINTIFFS, ALL CLASS PLAINTIFFS, THE MARCUS CORPORATION,
`BILL MCCAULEY, READ MCCAFFREY, HILLARY JAYNES, ANTHONY
`OLIVER, BERNADETTE MARTIN, BRYAN HUEY, JAMES EATON, PAUL
`KASHISHIAN, GIANNA VALDES, CHAD TINTROW, MATTHEW
`MORIARTY, ANDREW AMEND, IGOR GELMAN, ZACHARY DRAPER,
`SHAWN O’KEEFE, FRANCISCO ROBLETO, JR., MICHAEL THOMAS REID,
`
`

`

`PLYMOUTH OIL CORP., CLAM LAKE PARTNERS LLC,
`Plaintiffs,
`
`v.
`
`AMERICAN EXPRESS TRAVEL RELATED SERVICES COMPANY, INC.,
`AMERICAN EXPRESS COMPANY,
`Defendants-Appellees,
`
`SUSAN BURDETTE,
`Defendant,
`
`CIRCUIT CITY LIQUIDATING TRUST, THE RSH LIQUIDATING TRUST,
`HOLIDAY COMPANIES, GANDER MOUNTAIN COMPANY,
`COMMONWEALTH HOTELS, INC., KEILA RAVELO,
`Intervenors.*
`
`
`
`On Appeal from the United States District Court
`for the Eastern District of New York
`
`
`ARGUED: DECEMBER 16, 2020
`DECIDED: NOVEMBER 22, 2021
`
`
`CHIN, BIANCO, and MENASHI, Circuit Judges.
`
`Before:
`
`The plaintiffs-appellants are commercial merchants that sought
`monetary and injunctive relief under both federal and California
`antitrust laws against the defendants-appellees—American Express
`
`
`* The Clerk of Court is directed to amend the caption as set forth above.
`
`2
`
`

`

`Travel Related Services Co., Inc., and American Express Co.—alleging
`that the appellees’ anti-steering rules caused merchant fees to rise
`across the market. The appellants do not accept American Express
`cards and therefore proceeded under an “umbrella” theory of
`liability. The district court considered the four “efficient enforcer”
`factors, concluded that the appellants lacked antitrust standing, and
`dismissed the claims. The appellants challenge that holding, arguing
`that the four efficient-enforcer factors support antitrust standing for
`the “umbrella” plaintiffs in this case.
`
`factors structure a
`We disagree. The efficient-enforcer
`proximate cause analysis according to which there must be a
`sufficiently close relationship between the alleged injury and the
`alleged antitrust violation to establish antitrust standing. Here, that
`relationship is lacking. After considering the efficient-enforcer factors
`and the relevant state laws, we AFFIRM.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`SCOTT MARTIN, Hausfeld LLP, New York, NY (Michael
`D. Hausfeld, Hausfeld LLP, Washington, DC, and Irving
`Scher, Jeanette Bayoumi, and Kimberly Fetsick, Hausfeld
`LLP, New York, NY, on the brief), for Plaintiffs-Appellants.
`
`EVAN R. CHESLER (Peter T. Barbur, Kevin J. Orsini, and
`Rory A. Leraris, on the brief), Cravath, Swaine & Moore
`LLP, New York, NY, for Defendants-Appellees.
`
`Eric F. Citron, Goldstein & Russell, P.C., Bethesda, MD,
`for Amici Curiae Eighteen Professors of Antitrust Law.
`
`
`3
`
`

`

`20–1766
`In re American Express Anti-Steering Rules Antitrust Litigation
`MENASHI, Circuit Judge:
`
`
`
`The appellants, on behalf of a class of commercial merchants,
`allege that the Anti-Steering Rules promulgated by the appellees, the
`American Express Company and American Express Travel Related
`Services Company, Inc. (together, “Amex”), violate the antitrust laws.
`
`The appellants do not accept American Express cards but claim
`to be harmed by Amex’s policies nevertheless. These merchants “seek
`monetary and injunctive relief for overcharges paid to Visa,
`MasterCard, and Discover,” not to Amex, “caused by Amex’s
`imposition of ‘Anti-Steering Rules’ in its agreements with merchants
`who accept Amex cards.” Appellants’ Br. 1-2. The appellants claim
`that “Amex’s Anti-Steering Rules have stifled interbrand competition
`throughout the relevant market, causing the credit card transaction
`fees charged to Appellants by Visa, MasterCard, and Discover to
`prevail at supracompetitive levels under Amex’s pricing umbrella.”
`Id. at 2.
`
`The U.S. District Court for the Eastern District of New York
`(Garaufis, J.) dismissed the appellants’ claims under Federal Rule of
`Civil Procedure 12(b)(6) and ruled that the class lacked antitrust
`standing because it did not include “efficient enforcers” of the
`antitrust laws relative to Amex’s challenged anticompetitive conduct.
`In re Am. Express Anti-Steering Rules Antitrust Litig., 433 F. Supp. 3d
`395, 407-13 (E.D.N.Y. 2020). The appellants “seek reversal of the
`district court’s dismissal of
`their claims because Amex’s
`anticompetitive conduct has directly injured them, and recognizing
`their standing would ensure efficient enforcement of the antitrust
`laws.” Appellants’ Br. 2. Amex contends that the district court was
`correct that the appellants “lack antitrust standing because they are
`
`

`

`not efficient enforcers” of the antitrust laws and the alleged damages
`are “too indirect” and “speculative.” Appellees’ Br. 3-4.
`
`We affirm the district court’s judgment. To determine whether
`a party can sue under the antitrust laws—whether the party has
`“antitrust standing”—we apply the “efficient enforcer” test. The
`efficient-enforcer test is an elaboration on the proximate cause
`requirement of Associated General Contractors of California, Inc. v.
`California State Council of Carpenters (AGC), 459 U.S. 519, 535-36 (1983).
`In cases of economic harm, proximate cause is demarcated by the
`“first step” rule, which limits liability to parties injured at the first step
`of the causal chain of the defendants’ actions. See id. at 534. Here, at
`the first step, Amex restrained trade to raise its own prices; only later
`did its competitors follow suit. Because the appellants were harmed
`at that later step, the claims here fail the first-step test. After
`considering the four AGC factors, we conclude that—taking the
`allegations of the complaint as true—the appellants are not efficient
`enforcers of the antitrust laws and therefore lack antitrust standing.
`
`BACKGROUND1
`
`The appellants challenge Amex’s Anti-Steering Rules, or what
`Amex calls its non-discrimination provisions, contained in its Card
`Acceptance Agreement with merchants. The appellants allege that
`“Amex’s Anti-Steering Rules unreasonably restrain interbrand price
`competition with the other major [credit card] networks because the
`Rules: (1) stifle
`interbrand competition among the networks;
`(2) impose supracompetitive merchant fees, without corresponding
`
`1 For purposes of this appeal, we accept as true all facts alleged in the second
`amended complaint (“SAC”). Henry v. County of Nassau, 6 F.4th 324, 328 (2d
`Cir. 2021).
`
`5
`
`

`

`offsetting credit card user economic benefits; (3) cause the overall
`price of credit card transactions to rise above competitive levels
`marketwide, because the other credit card networks would not
`benefit competitively by reducing their merchant fees; and (4) raise
`consumer retail prices throughout the economy, thereby reducing
`output.” Appellants’ Br. 4; see also Am. Express Anti-Steering, 433
`F. Supp. 3d at 401.
`
`I
`
`The credit card industry is divided among four competing
`networks: Amex, Visa, MasterCard, and Discover. Ohio v. Am. Express
`Co., 138 S. Ct. 2274, 2282 (2018). The market is characterized by high
`barriers to entry. New entrants face a “chicken-and-egg” problem
`because “merchants value a payment system only if a sufficient
`number of cardholders use it and cardholders value a payment card
`only if a sufficient number of merchants accept it.”2
`
`Credit card networks such as Amex “operate what economists
`call a ‘two-sided platform,’” which “offers different products or
`services to two different groups who both depend on the platform to
`intermediate between them.” Ohio, 138 S. Ct. at 2280.3 Amex provides
`credit-card services to both “merchants,” who accept Amex as
`payment, “and cardholders,” who use Amex to make payments. Ohio,
`138 S. Ct. at 2279-80. Both parties are necessary; “no credit-card
`
`
`2 Benjamin Klein, Andres V. Lerner, Kevin M. Murphy & Lacey L. Plache,
`Competition in Two-Sided Markets: The Antitrust Economics of Payment Card
`Interchange Fees, 73 ANTITRUST L.J. 571, 584 (2006).
`3 See also D. Daniel Sokol, Rethinking the Efficiency of the Common Law, 95
`NOTRE DAME L. REV. 795, 803 (2019) (“The value of the two-sided market (or
`platform) is the ability to make matches across both sides of the market.”).
`
`6
`
`

`

`transaction can occur unless both the merchant and the cardholder
`simultaneously agree to use the same credit-card network.” Id. at
`2280.
`
`While credit card companies often charge cardholders an
`annual fee, all credit card companies charge merchants a fee for every
`transaction processed.4 According to the appellants, Amex charges
`higher merchant fees than its competitors. To avoid the higher fees,
`merchants—in the absence of any restraint prohibiting the practice—
`might “steer” their customers toward using another form of payment.
`“Steering” could be done in different ways, such as simply by asking,
`offering benefits for using other payment methods, or imposing a
`surcharge on the use of Amex cards.5
`
`Steering allows for price signals between merchant and
`customer. Without steering, “consumers do not internalize the full
`costs of their choice of payment system.”6 Steering also may prevent
`Amex from charging higher fees because merchants will steer
`customers toward cards with lower fees. In sum, “American Express
`dislikes steering; the merchants like it; and the shoppers may benefit
`from it, whether because merchants will offer them incentives to use
`
`
`4 See Timothy J. Muris, Payment Card Regulation and the (Mis)application of the
`Economics of Two-Sided Markets, 2005 COLUM. BUS. L. REV. 515, 522 (2005).
`5 See Klein et al., supra note 2, at 586-87.
`6 Adam J. Levitin, Priceless? The Social Costs of Credit Card Merchant
`Restraints, 45 HARV. J. ON LEGIS. 1, 11 (2008); see also id. at 3 (“[S]ome
`consumers end up paying higher or lower prices for the transaction than
`they would have if the merchant charged prices that varied with the cost of
`accepting payment.”).
`
`7
`
`

`

`less expensive cards or in the form of lower retail prices overall.” Ohio,
`138 S. Ct. at 2292 (Breyer, J., dissenting).
`
`Amex has discouraged steering by inserting anti-steering
`provisions into its contracts with merchants. Pursuant to Amex’s
`Anti-Steering Rules, merchants may not:
`
`•
`
`indicate or imply that they prefer, directly or
`indirectly, any Other Payment Products over Amex
`Cards;
`
`• try to dissuade cardholders from using their Amex
`Card;
`
`• criticize or mischaracterize the Amex Card or any of
`Amex’s services or programs;
`
`• try to persuade or prompt cardholders to use any
`Other Payment Products or any other method of
`payment (e.g., payment by check);
`
`•
`
`impose any restriction, conditions, or disadvantages
`when the Card is accepted that are not imposed
`equally on all Other Payment Products, except for
`ACH funds transfer, cash, and checks;
`
`• engage in activities that harm Amex’s business or the
`American Express Brand (or both);
`
`• or promote any Other Payment Products (except the
`Merchant’s own private label card that they issue for
`use solely at their Establishments) more actively than
`the Merchant promotes Amex.
`
`Am. Express Anti-Steering, 433 F. Supp. 3d at 404 (alterations omitted).
`
`8
`
`

`

`The appellants allege that these Anti-Steering Rules, when
`combined with Amex’s higher merchant fees, have raised fees
`throughout the industry. Competing networks “have no economic
`incentive to compete in the market by offering lower merchant fees
`[because] merchants cannot educate cardholders and
`[steer]
`transactions to the cards with lower fees.” Appellants’ Br. 7. Because
`“lower-fee competitor[s] cannot gain market share” by competing on
`price, all competing networks raise prices. Id. This effect is
`widespread because “most large merchants, according to Plaintiffs,
`do accept Amex, meaning that the credit card companies would have
`little incentive to tailor contracts for relatively insignificant individual
`merchants who do not.” Am. Express Anti-Steering, 433 F. Supp. 3d at
`415.
`
`II
`
`The Anti-Steering Rules have been litigated for over a decade.
`Merchants have been filing suits since the 2000s. See generally Rite-Aid
`Corp. v. Am. Express Travel Related Servs. Co., 708 F. Supp. 2d 257, 260
`(E.D.N.Y. 2010). “In October 2010, the Department of Justice and the
`attorneys general of eighteen states filed the Government Action
`against Amex, MasterCard, and Visa” challenging each company’s
`version of the Anti-Steering Rules. In re Am. Express Anti-Steering
`Rules Antitrust Litig., No. 08-CV-2315, 2016 WL 748089, at *2 (E.D.N.Y.
`Jan. 7, 2016). “Visa and MasterCard entered into consent decrees with
`the Government on the same day that the Government Action was
`initiated. Only Amex remained as a defendant.” Id. at *2 n.5. After a
`bench trial, the district court ruled for the government, concluding
`that it had shown by a preponderance of the evidence that the Anti-
`Steering Rules violated § 1 of the Sherman Act. United States v. Am.
`Express Co., 88 F. Supp. 3d 143, 238 (E.D.N.Y. 2015). Our court
`
`9
`
`

`

`reversed that judgment, holding that the district court erred in not
`requiring the government to show harm to consumers “accounting
`for consumers on both sides of the platform.” United States v. Am.
`Express Co., 838 F.3d 179, 206-07 (2d Cir. 2016). The Supreme Court
`then affirmed. Ohio, 138 S. Ct. at 2290.
`
`“Following the Supreme Court’s affirmance of the dismissal of
`the Government Action, matters resumed in the [Merchant Plaintiff]
`Actions.” Am. Express Anti-Steering, 433 F. Supp. 3d at 405. The
`merchant plaintiffs—including the appellants here—filed the SAC on
`December 17, 2018. The SAC sought monetary and equitable relief
`“on behalf of two putative classes: (1) a class of merchants who accept
`Amex cards … (the ‘Amex Class’); and (2) a class of merchants who
`do not accept Amex cards and who have no contract with Amex (the
`‘Non-Amex Class’).” Id. at 401. Within both classes, subclasses of
`plaintiffs sought relief under California law. Id. at 402, 405.
`
`On January 15, 2020, the district court ruled in Amex’s favor.
`Id. at 417. It first granted Amex’s motion to compel arbitration of the
`Amex Class’s claims. See id. at 405-07. It then granted Amex’s motion
`to dismiss the Non-Amex Class’s claims. See id. at 407-16. Specifically,
`the district court held that “the Non-Amex Class has not established
`federal antitrust standing.” Id. at 413. Applying the “efficient
`enforcer” test, id. at 408; see Balaklaw v. Lovell, 14 F.3d 793, 797 n.9 (2d
`Cir. 1994) (endorsing the efficient-enforcer test), the district court
`concluded that all four efficient-enforcer factors indicated that the
`appellants lacked antitrust standing. Am. Express Anti-Steering, 433
`F. Supp. 3d at 407-13. For similar reasons, the district court concluded
`that the appellants lacked antitrust standing under California’s
`Cartwright Act and Unfair Competition Law as well. Id. at 413-16. On
`May 14, 2020, the district court entered an order of partial final
`
`10
`
`

`

`judgment pursuant to Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 54(b). On June
`8, 2020, the appellants timely appealed.
`
`DISCUSSION
`
`“We review a district court’s grant of a motion to dismiss de
`novo, accepting as true all factual claims in the complaint and drawing
`all reasonable inferences in the plaintiff’s favor.” Henry, 6 F.4th at 328
`(internal quotation marks omitted). The appellants argue that the
`district court erred when it dismissed their claims under the Clayton
`Act and under California antitrust law. We address each claim in turn.
`
`I
`
`The appellants contend that the district court erred in
`dismissing their federal antitrust claim. The appellants brought that
`claim under the Clayton Act, which provides a private right of action
`for injuries “by reason of anything forbidden in the antitrust laws.”
`15 U.S.C. § 15(a). The district court dismissed the claim on the ground
`that the appellants lacked antitrust standing. See Am. Express Anti-
`Steering, 433 F. Supp. 3d at 407-08. We agree with the district court’s
`conclusion.
`
`“It is a well-established principle that, while the United States
`is authorized to sue anyone violating the federal antitrust laws, a
`private plaintiff must demonstrate ‘standing.’” Daniel v. Am. Bd. of
`Emergency Med., 428 F.3d 408, 436 (2d Cir. 2005). We have explained
`that “[a]ntitrust standing is a threshold, pleading-stage inquiry” and
`that “when a complaint by its terms fails to establish this requirement
`we must dismiss it as a matter of law.” Gatt Commc’ns, Inc. v. PMC
`Assocs., L.L.C., 711 F.3d 68, 75 (2d Cir. 2013) (quoting NicSand, Inc. v.
`3M Co., 507 F.3d 442, 450 (6th Cir. 2007) (en banc)). This requirement
`
`11
`
`

`

`“prevents private plaintiffs from recovering damages under” the
`Clayton Act “merely by showing injury causally linked to an illegal
`presence in the market.” Id. at 76 (internal quotation marks and
`alteration omitted).
`
`To demonstrate antitrust standing, a private plaintiff must
`show both that (1) “it suffered a special kind of antitrust injury” and
`that (2) “it is a suitable plaintiff to pursue the alleged antitrust
`violations and thus is an efficient enforcer of the antitrust laws.” Id.
`(internal quotation marks omitted). Whether a plaintiff is an “efficient
`enforcer” depends on the four factors the Supreme Court identified
`in AGC. 459 U.S. at 540-45. Those factors are (1) “the directness or
`indirectness of the asserted injury”; (2) “the existence of more direct
`victims” or the “existence of an identifiable class of persons whose
`self-interest would normally motivate them to vindicate the public
`interest in antitrust enforcement”; (3) the extent to which the claim is
`“highly speculative”; and (4) “the importance of avoiding either the
`risk of duplicate recoveries on the one hand, or the danger of complex
`apportionment of damages on the other.” Id.; see also Gelboim v. Bank
`of Am. Corp., 823 F.3d 759, 772 (2d Cir. 2016). “[T]he weight to be given
`the various factors will necessarily vary with the circumstances of
`particular cases.” Daniel, 428 F.3d at 443.
`
`In this case, the appellants claim to have antitrust standing
`under a so-called “umbrella” theory. The classic “umbrella” scenario
`occurs when “[a] cartel cuts output, which elevates price throughout
`the market.” U.S. Gypsum Co. v. Ind. Gas Co., 350 F.3d 623, 627 (7th Cir.
`2003). Because of that price umbrella, “customers of fringe firms
`(sellers that have not joined the cartel) pay this higher price, and thus
`suffer antitrust injury, just like customers of the cartel’s members.” Id.
`In other words, the umbrella theory “seeks to hold price-fixers liable
`
`12
`
`

`

`for harm allegedly flowing from the illegal conduct even though the
`price-fixing defendants received none of the illegal gains and were
`uninvolved in their competitors’ pricing decisions.” In re Coordinated
`Pretrial Proceedings in Petroleum Prods. Antitrust Litig., 691 F.2d 1335,
`1339 (9th Cir. 1982). The appellant merchants in this case do not have
`a contractual relationship with Amex such that the Anti-Steering
`Rules apply to the appellants directly. Rather, the appellants argue
`that—as in a classic umbrella scenario—Amex’s practices provide an
`umbrella under which the other credit card companies that do have a
`relationship with the appellants also raise prices.
`
`The district court declined to determine whether the appellants
`had established an antitrust injury because it concluded that the
`appellants were not efficient enforcers of the antitrust laws and for
`that reason lacked antitrust standing. We likewise need not address
`antitrust injury. Because the four efficient-enforcer factors do not
`establish antitrust standing, we affirm the district court’s judgment.
`
`A
`
`The first efficient-enforcer factor asks whether “the violation
`was a direct or remote cause of the injury.” Gelboim, 823 F.3d at 772.
`This factor turns on “familiar principles of proximate causation.”
`Lotes Co. v. Hon Hai Precision Indus. Co., 753 F.3d 395, 412 (2d Cir. 2014).
`
`Proximate cause stands for the proposition that “the judicial
`remedy cannot encompass every conceivable harm that can be traced
`to alleged wrongdoing.” AGC, 459 U.S. at 536. It encompasses “the
`judicial tools used to limit a person’s responsibility for the
`consequences of that person’s own acts” and “reflects ideas of what
`justice demands, or of what is administratively possible and
`convenient.” Holmes v. Sec. Inv. Prot. Corp., 503 U.S. 258, 268 (1992)
`
`13
`
`

`

`(internal quotation marks omitted). This principle limits antitrust
`liability beyond a certain point. Given the “ripples of harm” that
`antitrust violations may have in the economy, the Supreme Court has
`said that “[i]t is reasonable to assume that Congress did not intend to
`allow every person tangentially affected by an antitrust violation to
`maintain an action to recover threefold damages for the injury to his
`business or property.” Blue Shield of Va. v. McCready, 457 U.S. 465, 476-
`77 (1982). Therefore, “despite the broad wording of § 4 [of the Clayton
`Act] there is a point beyond which the wrongdoer should not be held
`liable.” Id. at 477 (quoting Ill. Brick Co. v. Illinois, 431 U.S. 720, 760
`(1977) (Brennan, J., dissenting)).
`
`In the context of antitrust standing, proximate cause generally
`follows the first-step rule. When the Clayton Act was enacted, the
`Supreme Court has explained, Congress understood “the judicial
`gloss” expressed by Justice Holmes: “The general tendency of the law,
`in regard to damages at least, is not to go beyond the first step.” AGC,
`459 U.S. at 534 (quoting S. Pac. Co. v. Darnell-Taenzer Lumber Co., 245
`U.S. 531, 533 (1918) (Holmes, J.)).7 The first-step rule requires “some
`
`
`7 In other words, the law “does not attribute remote consequences to a
`defendant,” even if those consequences are foreseeable. Darnell-Taenzer, 245
`U.S. at 533. Barring liability for foreseeable harms is not unusual. Such
`limits on liability can be found, for example, in the economic loss rule, see
`Akron Corp. v. M/T Cantigny, 706 F.2d 151, 153 (5th Cir. 1983) (noting that “a
`party may not recover for economic losses not associated with physical
`damages” so as “to prevent limitless liability for negligence and the filing
`of law suits of a highly speculative nature”); see also RESTATEMENT (THIRD)
`OF TORTS: LIAB. FOR ECON. HARM § 1 cmt. c(1) (Am. L. Inst. 2020) (noting that
`one of the rationales for limiting tort liability for economic loss is that
`“[e]conomic losses proliferate more easily than losses of other kinds” even
`though such losses “may be at least generally foreseeable to the person who
`commits the negligent act”), and other limitations on liability for
`
`14
`
`

`

`direct relation between the injury asserted and the injurious conduct
`alleged.” Bank of Am. Corp. v. City of Miami, 137 S. Ct. 1296, 1306 (2017)
`(quoting Holmes, 503 U.S. at 268). Under the rule, injuries that happen
`at the first step following the harmful behavior are considered
`proximately caused by that behavior. Accordingly, “[d]irectness in
`the antitrust context means close in the chain of causation.” Gatt
`Commc’ns, 711 F.3d at 78 (quoting IBM Corp. v. Platform Sols., Inc., 658
`F. Supp. 2d 603, 611 (S.D.N.Y. 2009)). As Justice Stevens, the author of
`AGC, observed, the Supreme Court’s “interpretation of § 4 has …
`adhered to Justice Holmes’ observation that the ‘general tendency of
`the law, in regard to damages at least, is not to go beyond the first
`step.’” Verizon Commc’ns Inc. v. Law Offs. of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540
`U.S. 398, 417 (2004) (Stevens, J., concurring in the judgment) (quoting
`S. Pac. Co., 245 U.S. at 533).
`
`Our court has repeatedly followed the first-step rule in the
`antitrust context. In Paycom Billing Services. v. MasterCard International,
`Inc., we held that a merchant, Paycom, did not suffer a direct injury
`
`
`negligence, see 532 Madison Ave. Gourmet Foods, Inc. v. Finlandia Ctr., Inc., 96
`N.Y.2d 280, 289 (2001) (“Absent a duty running directly to the injured
`person there can be no liability in damages, however careless the conduct
`or foreseeable the harm.”), and for negligent misrepresentation, see
`RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF TORTS: LIAB. FOR ECON. HARM § 5 cmt. b
`(“Liabilities that expand as easily as words travel would … become
`indeterminate and unduly widespread in many cases.”). Even when the law
`extends a right to recover for derivative injury—such as emotional distress
`from witnessing another’s accident—that right is often confined to close
`relations and excludes others in ways unrelated to foreseeability. Robert L.
`Rabin, Tort Recovery for Negligently Inflicted Economic Loss: A Reassessment,
`37 STAN. L. REV. 1513, 1522 (1985). The “specter of collateral claims, virtually
`unlimited
`in number, as a result of any given accident”—not
`foreseeability—informs these limitations. Id. at 1525.
`
`15
`
`

`

`from MasterCard’s practice of forbidding its member banks from
`dealing with other card companies. 467 F.3d 283, 293 (2d Cir. 2006).
`Paycom’s theory was that, absent that practice, MasterCard would
`have faced more competition from Discover and American Express,
`and it would have then adopted more favorable policies toward
`Paycom. Id. That was not enough to establish antitrust standing; we
`concluded that “any injury suffered by Paycom was indirect and
`flowed from the injuries suffered by Discover and American
`Express.” Id. We similarly held that the injury suffered in Gatt
`Communications was indirect. 711 F.3d at 78-79. In that case, Gatt
`Communications alleged that PMC Associates had formed a price-
`fixing conspiracy for the sale of Vertex radio equipment to
`government agencies, and when Gatt sought to defect, its “Dealer
`Agreement”—through which it was able to sell that brand of radio
`equipment in the first place—was terminated. Id. at 71-73. Gatt argued
`that it was entitled to damages for the commissions it would have
`received absent the anticompetitive conduct. Id. at 74. We held that
`Gatt was harmed “only incidentally” and that “[i]f there are direct
`victims of the alleged conspiracy, they are the state agencies, not
`Gatt.” Id. at 78-79. Most recently, in IQ Dental Supply, Inc. v. Henry
`Schein, Inc., we determined that IQ Dental Supply, though injured by
`a boycott of the third-party online portal through which IQ sold its
`goods, lacked antitrust standing to challenge that boycott. 924 F.3d 57,
`65 (2d Cir. 2019). Because the harm to IQ “resulted from injury” to the
`third-party portal, the antitrust claims were “derivative and indirect.”
`Id.
`
`In this case, the appellants did not suffer a direct injury from
`the alleged antitrust violation. At the first step, Amex raised the price
`for Amex-accepting merchants through the Anti-Steering Rules.
`
`16
`
`

`

`Amex did not raise the appellants’ fees. Nor could it have: the
`appellants do not accept American Express cards. Similar to the
`holdings in Gatt Communications and IQ Dental Supply, if there are
`“direct victims,” those victims are the merchants to which Amex’s
`Anti-Steering Rules applied. Gatt Commc’ns, 711 F.3d at 78-79; IQ
`Dental Supply, 924 F.3d at 65. The appellants were allegedly injured
`when Amex’s competitors, covered by Amex’s price umbrella, raised
`their own prices. In the appellants’ words, Amex’s imposition of
`increased merchant fees “enabled” the competitor companies “to
`increase their own merchant fees.” Appellants’ Br. 10. Yet Amex
`“enabl[ing]” other credit card companies to raise the appellants’ fees
`does not establish the “direct relation” between injury and antitrust
`violation that the first-step rule requires. Bank of Am. Corp., 137 S. Ct.
`at 1306.
`
`Given the allegations in the SAC, we hold that the appellants’
`injuries did not occur at the first step following Amex’s conduct. The
`injuries, therefore, were not proximately caused by Amex; the alleged
`antitrust violation was instead a “remote” cause of the injuries.
`
`B
`
`The second efficient-enforcer factor considers the “existence of
`an identifiable class of persons whose self-interest would normally
`motivate them to vindicate the public
`interest
`in antitrust
`enforcement.” IQ Dental Supply, 924 F.3d at 65 (quoting Daniel, 428
`F.3d at 443). For this factor, we ask whether “[d]enying the [plaintiff]
`a remedy on the basis of its allegations” is “likely to leave a significant
`antitrust violation undetected or unremedied.” AGC, 459 U.S. at 542;
`see also Paycom, 467 F.3d at 294. “[T]he presence of plaintiffs who are
`better situated to vindicate the antitrust
`laws,” though not
`
`17
`
`

`

`dispositive, “is relevant to this second factor.” IQ Dental Supply, 924
`F.3d at 66. The existence of such plaintiffs “diminishes the justification
`for allowing a more remote party … to perform the office of a private
`attorney general.” AGC, 459 U.S. at 542.
`
`This factor also counsels against antitrust standing here. In IQ
`Dental Supply, we concluded that antitrust standing based on the
`second factor was unlikely because “IQ [was] further removed from
`the harm caused by the Defendants than the parties directly affected
`by the boycott that have already sued the Defendants.” IQ Dental
`Supply, 924 F.3d at 66. The same argument applies here. As noted, the
`merchants who have a relationship with Amex were harmed at the
`first step by Amex’s Anti-Steering Rules. And those merchants have
`already sued Amex. Am. Express Anti-Steering, 433 F. Supp. 3d at 401-
`02. We follow our precedent in holding that “the second efficient-
`enforcer factor weighs against … antitrust standing” in this case. IQ
`Dental Supply, 924 F.3d at 66.
`
`C
`
`The third efficient-enforcer factor concerns the extent to which
`the claim is “highly speculative.” AGC, 459 U.S. at 542. “[H]ighly
`speculative damages is a sign that a given plaintiff is an inefficient
`engine of enforcement.” Gelboim, 823 F.3d at 779. Under this factor,
`we ask whether there would be “a high degree of speculation in a
`damages calculation.” IQ Dental Supply, 924 F.3d at 66-67. When an
`injury is “derivative” rather than direct, the potential recovery is often
`“highly speculative.” Id. at 67. We also consider whether the “alleged
`effects on the [plaintiff] may have been produced by independent
`factors.” AGC, 459 U.S. at 542.
`
`18
`
`

`

`Whether this factor weighs in favor of antitrust standing is a
`close question. The SAC presents a compelling prima facie case of
`foreseeable damages, given the allegation that Amex exercises market
`power and the district court’s finding in the Government Action that
`the “prohibitions on merchant steering” have “enabled … higher all-
`in fees.” Am. Express Co., 88 F. Supp. 3d at 216.8 Yet the fact that the
`appellants have suffered an “indirect” injury, and the accompanying
`uncertainty of how eliminating Amex’s Anti-Steering Rules would
`affect its competitors’ merchant fees, suggest that a damages
`calculation would rely on some speculation. See AGC, 459 U.S. at 542.
`
`In any event, the third factor does not confer antitrust standing
`on the appellants. The four efficient-enforcer factors “need not be
`given equal weight,” and “the relative significance of each factor will
`depend on the circumstances of the particular case.” IQ Dental Supply,
`924 F.3d at 65. In particular, the Supreme Court has noted that the
`“potential difficulty in ascertaining and apportioning damages is not
`… an independent basis for denying standing where it is adequately
`
`
`8 In making this finding, the district court in the Government Action
`explained that from 1997 to 2009, “prohibitions on merchant steering”
`enabled

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket