throbber
22-1135-cv
`Heim v. Daniel
`
`UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
`FOR THE SECOND CIRCUIT
`
`
`August Term, 2022
`
`Argued: June 30, 2023 Decided: August 30, 2023
`
`Docket No. 22-1135-cv
`
`
`JOHN J. HEIM,
`
`Plaintiff-Appellant,
`
`— v. —
`
`BETTY DANIEL, ADRIAN MASTERS,
`
`Defendants-Appellees.*
`
`
`
`Before:
`
`LYNCH, BIANCO, and PÉREZ, Circuit Judges.
`
`
`
`This appeal concerns a First Amendment retaliation claim brought in the
`
`* The Clerk is respectfully directed to amend the caption to conform to the above.
`
`

`

`Northern District of New York by Plaintiff-Appellant John Heim, an adjunct
`professor of economics at SUNY Albany, who attributes his failure to advance
`within his department to his colleagues’ unfavorable view of the methodology he
`employs in his scholarship. The district court (Hurd, J.) granted summary
`judgment to Defendants, two of Heim’s colleagues who were involved in the
`hiring decisions at issue. Although we disagree with much of the district court’s
`reasoning, we nonetheless agree with its ultimate disposition. We hold that
`Garcetti v. Ceballos, 547 U.S. 410 (2006), does not apply to speech related to
`academic scholarship or teaching, and that Heim’s speech addressed matters of
`public concern, but that Heim’s First Amendment claim nonetheless fails because
`under Pickering v. Bd. of Educ., 391 U.S. 563 (1968), a public university’s interest in
`deciding for itself what skills, expertise, and academic perspectives it wishes to
`prioritize in its hiring and staffing decisions outweighs Heim’s asserted interest
`in competing for academic positions unencumbered by university decision-
`makers’ assessment of his academic speech. We therefore AFFIRM the judgment
`of the district court.
`
`
`
`PHILLIP G. STECK, Cooper Erving & Savage LLP, Albany, NY,
`for Plaintiff-Appellant.
`
`SARAH L. ROSENBLUTH, Assistant Solicitor General, Buffalo, NY
`(Letitia James, Attorney General; Barbara D.
`Underwood, Solicitor General; Andrea Oser, Deputy
`Solicitor General, on the brief), for Defendants-Appellees.
`
`DARPANA M. SHETH, Washington, DC, for Amicus Curiae
`Foundation for Individual Rights and Expression.
`
`
`
`2
`
`

`

`GERARD E. LYNCH, Circuit Judge:
`
`Plaintiff-Appellant John Heim, an adjunct professor of economics, appeals
`
`from a judgment of the United States District Court for the Northern District of
`
`New York (David N. Hurd, J.) granting summary judgment to his colleagues
`
`Betty Daniel and Adrian Masters (together, “Defendants”) who, as the relevant
`
`decision-makers in the Economics Department at the State University of New
`
`York at Albany (“SUNY Albany”1), declined to interview Heim for more
`
`desirable positions he believes he was qualified for. Heim’s challenge is premised
`
`on the allegation that Defendants rejected his candidacy in substantial part
`
`because he is a proponent of traditional Keynesian economics, an approach that
`
`Defendants consider to be outdated.
`
`Although we accept that factual premise underlying Heim’s appeal, we
`
`disagree with the legal theory it supports: that, under the First Amendment, a
`
`public university’s hiring decisions cannot be informed by methodological
`
`preference. Rather, applying the employer/employee interest-balancing
`
`framework first set forth in Pickering v. Bd. of Educ., 391 U.S. 563 (1968), we hold
`
`1 The institution is also referred to in the record as “The University at Albany”
`and, simply, “Albany.”
`
`3
`
`

`

`that a public university’s interest in deciding for itself what skills, expertise, and
`
`academic perspectives it wishes to prioritize in its hiring and staffing decisions
`
`outweighs Heim’s asserted interest in competing for academic positions
`
`unencumbered by university decision-makers’ assessment of the approach or
`
`methodology underlying his academic speech. We therefore AFFIRM the
`
`judgment of the district court.
`
`BACKGROUND
`
`I.
`
`Factual Background
`
`The following facts, which are largely drawn from Heim’s own testimony,
`
`are undisputed except where otherwise indicated, and are those that a reasonable
`
`factfinder could find, construing all ambiguities in Heim’s favor. See Cugini v.
`
`City of New York, 941 F.3d 604, 608 (2d Cir. 2019).
`
`A.
`
`The Parties
`
`Heim, an adjunct professor2 at SUNY Albany, initially brought this lawsuit
`
`against the entire SUNY system, SUNY Albany, its president Havidan Rodriguez,
`
`2 In his deposition, Heim explained that although his title was technically
`“visiting professor,” for “payroll purposes” he was “known as an adjunct
`professor or lecturer.” App’x 142, 151. All parties refer to him as an “adjunct.”
`
`4
`
`

`

`and two members of the SUNY Albany Economics Department (the
`
`“Department”): Professors Betty Daniel and Adrian Masters. Masters has chaired
`
`the Department since 2015, and was a member of its hiring committee at all
`
`relevant times. In addition to leading the Department prior to Masters, Daniel
`
`also chaired its hiring committee at all relevant times.
`
`B.
`
`Heim’s Professional Path
`
`Heim was a relative latecomer to academia. After receiving his Ph.D. in
`
`Political Economy from SUNY Albany in 1972, he worked in government as an
`
`econometrician (and in other similar capacities) for many years, interrupted only
`
`by his time in the mid-1980s obtaining a Master’s degree in Public
`
`Administration from Harvard. He began his teaching career in 1997, accepting a
`
`non-tenured position at Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute (“RPI”) where he
`
`eventually achieved the rank of (non-tenured) “full clinical professor.” App’x
`
`126.3 Heim’s duties at RPI “were limited to teaching and administration,”
`
`including teaching “Master[’s] and Ph.D.-level Advanced Macroeconomics I & II
`
`and Master’s level Econometrics” and supervising both undergraduate- and
`
`3 Because “[t]enure in that position was not available,” RPI never made any
`“decision on granting or denying [Heim] tenure.” App’x 528.
`
`5
`
`

`

`graduate-level research. Id. at 528.
`
`Around 2012, he accepted an adjunct position at SUNY Albany with a
`
`lighter teaching load that he felt would allow him to “concentrate more on
`
`research.” Id. That research, the methodology it employs, and the difference
`
`between that methodology and the approach favored by his colleagues at SUNY
`
`Albany are at the root of this dispute.
`
`C. Methodological Perspectives at SUNY Albany
`
`Heim describes himself as a traditional Keynesian economist. In Heim’s
`
`characterization, Keynesians “stud[y] the operation of the entire economy as a
`
`whole (in comparison to microeconomists who study the behavior of firms or
`
`sectors of the economy or particular markets),” with a particular focus on
`
`demand-driven government intervention. Appellant’s Br. 8. That perspective, he
`
`explains, derives from prominent 20th-century economist John Maynard Keynes’s
`
`view that “[w]hen consumers spend money in the economy, businesses respond
`
`by producing goods and services” to satisfy that robust aggregate demand,
`
`stimulating the macroeconomy; conversely, “when aggregate demand is lacking,
`
`the economy is depressed.” Id. For example, “[f]or Keynes, the Great Depression
`
`was caused by insufficient aggregate demand, that is[,] consumers having
`
`6
`
`

`

`insufficient purchasing power to drive the economy forward.” Id. Accordingly,
`
`Keynesian economics generally supports countering economic lulls with
`
`government intervention targeted at increasing consumers’ purchasing power
`
`through policies like tax cuts, heightened government spending, and increases in
`
`the money supply. That view represented a significant departure from prevailing
`
`early 20th-century perspectives, which effectively trusted to market forces to sort
`
`everything out in the long run. Keynes, of course, famously quipped that “[i]n the
`
`long run, we are all dead,” App’x 531, and the school of economics he founded
`
`enjoyed a run of prominence spanning several post-Great Depression decades.
`
`Rampant stagflation in the 1970s inspired many economists to re-evaluate.
`
`When traditional Keynesian methods were seen as unable to account for the
`
`oppressive mix of inflation, unemployment, and stagnant growth of the era, new
`
`approaches began to supplant Keynesianism. That reckoning was spurred by the
`
`so-called “Lucas Critique,”4 which posited that Keynesian models’ reliance on
`
`fixed coefficients to relate consumers’ disposable income to consumer spending
`
`did not account for the fact that consumers’ behaviors may vary based on their
`
`4 Named for its creator, University of Chicago economist and Nobel laureate
`Robert Lucas.
`
`7
`
`

`

`expectations for future government interventions – for example, by responding to
`
`a short-term tax cut aimed at increasing consumer purchasing power by instead
`
`saving newfound disposable income that Keynesian models would expect them
`
`(and policymakers would prefer them) to spend. That critique demanded a new
`
`way to predict macro, economy-wide, trends based on those kinds of micro,
`
`consumer-level, variables. So was born the “micro foundations of
`
`macroeconomics” school which, in Heim’s words, attempts to “extrapolate the
`
`behavior of the macro economy from the micro economy.” Id.
`
`One prominent technique employed under that banner, and by many post-
`
`Lucas Critique macroeconomists, is central to this lawsuit: “dynamic stochastic
`
`general equilibrium” (or “DSGE”) modeling. Heim characterizes DSGE as “a
`
`method that uses sophisticated mathematics such as logarithms to derive the
`
`behavior of the macro economy from the micro economy.” Id. at 532. DSGE’s
`
`proponents consider it a more flexible and robust technique than its forebears.
`
`They believe that by permitting macroeconomic indicators like economic output
`
`to be linked to coefficients that are sensitive to consumer expectations,
`
`researchers are able to model economic trends more dynamically and more
`
`realistically than would be possible using traditional Keynesian tools. To Heim,
`
`8
`
`

`

`though, none of this is really macroeconomics at all because it does not “deal
`
`with the behavior of the economy as a whole.” Id. at 535. In his view, “you cannot
`
`simply derive the macro from the micro.” Id.
`
`The merits of that debate5 are not for us to assess; judges are neither
`
`qualified nor commissioned to resolve academic debates among scholars in any
`
`particular discipline. What matters is that the debate exists at all, and that Heim
`
`– who practices traditional Keynesian economics6 – is on one side of it, while his
`
`colleagues at SUNY Albany – who do not – are on the other.
`
`D.
`
`Heim’s Work at SUNY Albany
`
`According to Heim, it did not take long for his colleagues’ “hostil[ity]”
`
`5 The parties, for example, dispute the extent to which Heim’s approach is or is
`not out-of-step and antiquated, precisely how ubiquitous and/or infallible the
`DSGE technique is or is not, and whether DSGE has invited a reversion to pre-
`Keynesian perspectives or is simply a technique used by modern economists of
`varying perspectives. Compare Appellant’s Br. 9 (“DSGE economists are said to be
`a modern version of neoclassical economists, the economists who emphasized
`market clearing before the advent of Keynes.”), with Appellee’s Br. 8
`(“Contemporary Keynesian analysis . . . often embraces DSGE techniques – it
`does not, as plaintiff claims, stand apart from DSGE.”).
`
`6 Heim describes his own work as “demand-driven Keynesianism, as Keynes
`himself would have recognized it,” employing a “highly detailed statistically
`based look at how the economy operates.” App’x 535.
`
`9
`
`

`

`towards his approach to affect the scope of his work within the Department.
`
`App’x 552. In his first semester at SUNY Albany, he taught a class on large-scale
`
`macroeconomic modeling. When Daniel took over as Chair, however, “she denied
`
`[Heim] the opportunity to continue teaching that class.” Id. at 528. Thereafter,
`
`although Heim maintained a full courseload teaching classes like “Principles of
`
`Economics” and “Economic Statistics,” he was never again assigned to teach
`
`macroeconomics.
`
`Meanwhile, Heim continued to forge ahead with his research, although as
`
`an adjunct he was not required to do so. For example, between 2017 and 2021 he
`
`published four books studying “every fiscal stimulus program going back to
`
`1960,” id. at 529, and as of February 2022, he had published 23 articles in
`
`economic journals. His research was publicized and celebrated by the university,
`
`including at a 2018 reception honoring several dozen “Authors & Artists” from
`
`across the College of Arts and Sciences, and a 2018 “Celebration of Scholarship”
`
`event featuring presentations from 45 SUNY Albany scholars across a range of
`
`disciplines. Id. at 573, 575.
`
`Heim remains employed as an adjunct at SUNY Albany. That is not
`
`because he always wanted to continue in that capacity, however. To the contrary,
`
`10
`
`

`

`at the heart of this lawsuit are three other positions in the Department that he
`
`was (or would have been) interested in, but for which he was never interviewed.
`
`1.
`
`The 2013 Position
`
`First, in December 2013, Heim learned of a tenure-track macroeconomics
`
`opening that the Department was in the process of filling. That was not an
`
`everyday occurrence; the Department is small, employing fewer than 20 faculty,
`
`only three or four of whom specialize in macroeconomics. Heim quickly reached
`
`out to Daniel by email to express his interest:
`
`I just found out last Friday at our holiday party that we
`were recruiting for a macroeconomics/Money and
`banking position. No one had mentioned this to me
`before, and I would have been interested in applying,
`had I known . . . .
`That said, my research interests are principally in large
`scale econometric modeling of the macroeconomy. . . . I
`am finalizing this year work on a 30-40 equation model
`of the macroeconomy, which could become known as
`the “SUNY Albany Econometric Model” . . . . I think my
`area of my research is likely to undergo a resurgence of
`interest in the near future[.]
`Of course, the department here at SUNY has already
`made a substantial investment in developing a micro
`foundations focus, and may be more interested in
`adding depth to its capacity in this area. Though I have
`taught graduate-level micro foundations courses, it is of
`course, an area substantially different from my own area
`
`11
`
`

`

`of interest and expertise. If this is the direction the
`department sees itself headed in, certainly someone far
`different than me would a better match for the
`department and its plans than I would be.
`
`Id. at 588-89. In response, Daniel confirmed that the Department was indeed
`
`looking for someone with a micro foundations focus, but that it nonetheless
`
`supported Heim’s ongoing, divergent research:
`
`Thanks for your interest in the macro position. You are
`correct that we are heavily invested in micro
`foundations of macro as this is the research trend in the
`top macro and general field journals. Since we expect
`our faculty to publish in these journals, we do intend to
`continue with this direction.
`I did consult with Adrian [Masters] . . . and we agree
`with you that your research differs from the course of
`research we want to pursue. I expect that we will hire a
`junior person recently trained in these techniques. I do
`want to encourage you to continue your research. It just
`does not match with the direction we are taking macro
`research in the Department.
`
`Id. at 588. The Department ultimately hired Yue Li, a recent Ph.D. with a micro
`
`foundations research focus who, in Heim’s estimation, had limited familiarity
`
`with traditional Keynesian modeling.
`
`2.
`
`The 2016 Position
`
`A few years later, in 2016, Heim learned that the Department had hired for
`
`12
`
`

`

`a full-time (non-tenure-track) lecturer position in financial economics – and that
`
`despite Heim’s background in that area, he had again never been approached
`
`about the opportunity, and in fact did not even learn of it until the job had
`
`already been filled by a fellow adjunct; the Department had sought and obtained
`
`a waiver from the university to make the offer to Lewis Segal, a former Goldman
`
`Sachs employee with a Ph.D. in economics from Northwestern, without going
`
`through the normal competitive hiring process. Although he concedes that Segal
`
`was qualified for the role, Heim maintains that he himself was “equally qualified,
`
`maybe a little bit more.” Id. at 199.
`
`3.
`
`The 2017 Position
`
`In August 2017, while having lunch with Daniel and Masters, Heim
`
`learned of another open tenure-track macroeconomics position in the
`
`Department. In October, he applied. But apart from an initial confirmation email
`
`from the university that his application had been received, several weeks passed
`
`without any response. Finally, in December, Heim followed up with Masters
`
`(now Chair of the Department) who told Heim that he was not being considered
`
`because his recommendations had not been received in time. The mix-up was
`
`apparently attributable to a technical snafu at the third-party online system
`
`13
`
`

`

`responsible for compiling application materials, leaving a frustrated Heim to
`
`wonder why no one had ever reached out to him about the missing documents
`
`even though it was widely known within the Department that he was applying.
`
`But all of that was a “red herring” anyway. Id. at 542. Eventually, after
`
`being pressed for further explanation by Heim, Masters put the “real reason,” id.,
`
`in an email:
`
`The department respects you and respects the fact that
`you continue to conduct your research as an adjunct
`professor. The technical reason we put down for not
`interviewing you is that we did not have letters and I
`told you that at the party. At the party I also gave you
`the “Cliff Notes” on the general feeling of the committee
`towards your application. Until now I have not given
`you chapter and verse because I am still happy to have
`you as a member of the department but you have now
`forced my hand on this. The fact is the committee did
`discuss your application and, as with many applicants
`with a track record, concluded that regardless of what
`any letters said we would not interview you for the
`position. Here is why:
`We are looking for someone who:
`1. Can teach and train students to conduct research in
`the modern (i.e. post Lucas Critique)
`macroeconomics that by your own admission
`everyone else but you and Ray Fair do[es]. Nothing
`in your credentials supports that possibility.
`2. Has a reasonable expectation of making tenure
`within the department within the 6 year tenure track
`
`14
`
`

`

`window. Here again the fact that you have a record
`speaks for itself. Nothing a letter writer can do can
`change that. The journals in which you have
`published do not achieve the standard that we expect
`for tenure. (Typically 4 articles in journals at the level
`of top field e.g. Journal of Monetary Economics or the
`International Economic Review.[)]
`3. Has sufficient synergies with our research agendas
`that we can learn from them and them from us with
`the possibility of constructive collaboration. Your
`work is not consistent with that expectation. Indeed,
`we rejected a number of applications that met the
`first 2 criteria above but they do New Keynesian
`macro that we do not appreciate.
`I hope you are not too discouraged by this and continue
`to teach and do your work within the department as an
`adjunct professor but the fact is that you will not be
`hired for this job.
`
`Id. at 597-98. Heim asked Masters to reconsider, “noting that DSGE economics
`
`had come under heavy criticism within the profession” including from two
`
`prominent economists, and urging that the Department would “benefit from
`
`having a recognized alternative, or at least by having a healthy debate on these
`
`issues in economics.” Id. at 545. Masters responded by simply dismissing those
`
`prominent critics as “old guys!” Id. The Department ultimately hired Ben Griffy, a
`
`recent Ph.D. whose research, like Masters’s, focused in part on macroeconomics
`
`and the labor market and who Heim believes also had limited familiarity with
`
`15
`
`

`

`traditional Keynesian methods.
`
`II.
`
`Procedural Background
`
`A. Early Proceedings
`
`Heim filed this lawsuit in July 2018, initially asserting three causes of
`
`action: (1) a claim for damages pursuant to 42 U.S.C. § 1983 against Daniel and
`
`Masters for “violat[ing] plaintiff’s right of freedom of speech while acting under
`
`color of” state law; (2) a claim pursuant to § 1983 for injunctive relief against
`
`SUNY Albany President Rodriguez in the form of a court order to “prevent
`
`ongoing discrimination against Keynesian economists” in violation of the First
`
`Amendment; and (3) an age discrimination claim under New York State’s Human
`
`Rights Law. App’x 64-67.7
`
`In September 2018, Defendants moved to dismiss the Complaint, and in a
`
`ruling from the bench, the district court granted that motion in part, dismissing
`
`the second and third causes of action. Along the way, Heim abandoned any claim
`
`7 The Complaint also foreshadowed that “[u]pon issuance of a right to sue letter
`by [the U.S. Equal Employment Opportunity Commission],” Heim would seek
`leave to add an age discrimination claim under the Age Discrimination in
`Employment Act. App’x 67. That never happened, and the district court therefore
`“decline[d] to consider any claim under the ADEA.” Heim v. Daniel, No.
`1:18-CV-836, 2022 WL 1472878, at *1 n.2 (N.D.N.Y. May 10, 2022). Heim does not
`challenge that decision on appeal.
`
`16
`
`

`

`against President Rodriguez, SUNY Albany, and the broader SUNY system,
`
`opting to pursue only the First Amendment retaliation claim against Daniel and
`
`Masters. Heim does not challenge any of that on appeal.
`
`B. Summary Judgment
`
`His appeal targets what happened next. After the parties exchanged
`
`discovery on Heim’s sole remaining claim – First Amendment retaliation –
`
`Defendants moved for summary judgment in January 2022.
`
`In May 2022, the district court granted that motion and entered judgment
`
`for Defendants, holding in relevant part that the First Amendment did not
`
`insulate Heim’s academic speech from adverse action by his public university
`
`employer. Heim v. Daniel, No. 1:18-CV-836, 2022 WL 1472878, at *14 (N.D.N.Y.
`
`May 10, 2022). It arrived at that conclusion applying two separate First
`
`Amendment frameworks in the alternative and reaching the same result under
`
`both, reasoning (1) that academic research and writing are part of a public
`
`university professor’s “official duties,” dooming Heim’s claims under Garcetti v.
`
`Ceballos, 547 U.S. 410, 421 (2006); and (2) that even if Garcetti did not apply,
`
`Heim’s “complex statistical modeling intended for consumption by a relatively
`
`narrow audience” did not address any matter of public concern, warranting
`
`17
`
`

`

`dismissal under Pickering. Heim, 2022 WL 1472878, at *14. The court also offered
`
`yet another alternative basis for its ruling: that because Heim did not meet the
`
`hiring committee’s stated qualifications for the position, “a reasonable jury
`
`would be compelled to conclude that defendants would not have promoted
`
`plaintiff . . . regardless of plaintiff’s protected speech.” Id. at *16.8
`
`DISCUSSION
`
`Heim challenges each of those points on appeal. He contends that the
`
`district court erred by, among other things, (1) misconstruing the role that Heim’s
`
`Keynesian viewpoints played in his colleagues’ hiring decisions; (2) applying
`
`Garcetti to academic speech at all; (3) concluding, under Pickering, that Heim’s
`
`speech did not address any matter of public concern; and (4) failing to properly
`
`“balance the employee’s First Amendment interests against the employer’s
`
`8 The court also (1) concluded “that to the extent Heim’s § 1983 claim is based on
`the general First Amendment right of ‘academic freedom,’ that claim must be
`dismissed, Heim, 2022 WL 1472878, at *7; (2) rejected Heim’s argument that this
`case should be analyzed under a “limited public forum” analysis, id. at *17
`(adding that “‘forums’ are places, not people”); and (3) remarked that although
`its conclusions as to the merits made it “unnecessary” to address qualified
`immunity, that defense “almost certainly applies” to Defendants’ conduct in this
`case, id. at *16 n.14. Heim does not challenge any of that on appeal, and because
`we resolve the sole claim he continues to press on other grounds, we have no
`occasion to express any view as to the merits of those observations.
`
`18
`
`

`

`legitimate interests.” Appellant’s Br. 49.
`
`Heim’s arguments are not altogether without merit. Although we affirm
`
`the district court’s ultimate disposition, we disagree with much of its reasoning.
`
`In particular, we disagree with its conclusions that Heim’s speech did not
`
`substantially motivate Defendants’ rejection of his candidacy, and that Heim’s
`
`speech did not address matters of public concern. We also join several other
`
`Circuits in recognizing that First Amendment retaliation claims founded upon
`
`speech that relates to academic scholarship or teaching are properly evaluated
`
`under Pickering’s employer/employee interest-balancing framework irrespective
`
`of whether, under Garcetti, that speech was part of an employee’s official duties.
`
`Ultimately, though, because Heim’s First Amendment retaliation claim cannot
`
`withstand that balancing test, it nonetheless fails.
`
`I.
`
`Legal Standards
`
`A. Standard of Review
`
`We review a district court’s grant of summary judgment de novo, “resolving
`
`all ambiguities and drawing all reasonable inferences” in favor of the
`
`non-movant. Woolf v. Strada, 949 F.3d 89, 92-93 (2d Cir. 2020) (internal quotation
`
`marks omitted). We affirm “only if there is no genuine issue of material fact and
`
`19
`
`

`

`the prevailing party was entitled to judgment as a matter of law.” Harris v. Miller,
`
`818 F.3d 49, 57 (2d Cir. 2016) (internal quotation marks omitted).
`
`B. First Amendment Retaliation
`
`To establish a prima facie First Amendment retaliation claim, a plaintiff
`
`must show (1) “that the speech or conduct at issue was protected” from the
`
`particular retaliatory act alleged; (2) that the retaliatory act qualifies as an
`
`“adverse action [taken] against the plaintiff”; and (3) “that there was a causal
`
`connection between the protected speech and the adverse action.” Shara v.
`
`Maine-Endwell Cent. Sch. Dist., 46 F.4th 77, 82 (2d Cir. 2022) (internal quotation
`
`marks omitted). However, “[e]ven if the plaintiff makes out a prima facie
`
`retaliation claim, a government defendant may still receive summary judgment if
`
`it establishes its entitlement to a relevant defense.” Anemone v. Metro. Transp.
`
`Auth., 629 F.3d 97, 114 (2d Cir. 2011).
`
`The district court held, and Defendants do not dispute on appeal, that the
`
`Department’s refusal to hire Heim for the 2017 position qualifies as an adverse
`
`action.9 We therefore address below only the other, contested, elements of a First
`
`9 Nor, for the most part, could Defendants dispute that point. “In a First
`Amendment retaliation case, a government employer’s response to speech
`
`20
`
`

`

`Amendment retaliation claim.
`
`constitutes an adverse action if it would deter a similarly situated individual of
`ordinary firmness from exercising his or her constitutional rights.” Connelly v.
`County of Rockland, 61 F.4th 322, 325 (2d Cir. 2023) (internal quotation marks
`omitted). This is a less “demanding” (that is, easier to satisfy) standard than the
`“materially adverse change in the terms and conditions of employment” test that
`we use to determine an “adverse action” in other employment contexts. E.g.,
`Zelnik v. Fashion Inst. of Tech., 464 F.3d 217, 225 (2d Cir. 2006) (internal quotation
`marks omitted). For purposes of First Amendment retaliation, an adverse action
`may include, among other things, “discharging, . . . demoting, reducing the pay,
`or reprimanding an employee” and, as especially relevant here, both “refusing to
`hire” and “refusing to promote” an applicant. Montero v. City of Yonkers, 890 F.3d
`386, 401 (2d Cir. 2018). Whether the 2017 decision not to interview Heim is better
`understood as a refusal to promote – a characterization Defendants have
`questioned, see App’x 872 (Daniel testifying: “The position of adjunct does not
`have the concept of promotion. An adjunct is a dead-end position. . . . The
`assistant professor position is a completely different position.”) – or a refusal to
`hire, it indisputably satisfies the “adverse action” requirement.
`The earlier acts of alleged retaliation present closer questions. The district
`court held that the circumstances surrounding the 2013 and 2016 hires did not
`amount to “sufficiently adverse actions,” emphasizing that Heim did not actually
`apply for either position, and brushing aside Heim’s arguments that “Daniel
`should not have discouraged him from applying” in 2013 and that the
`Department had “followed an improper internal or administrative process” in
`2016. Heim, 2022 WL 1472878, at *14. Because we reject Heim’s claim for other
`reasons, we need not decide whether those conclusions (which Heim does not
`challenge on appeal) faithfully reflect our permissive and fact-specific “adversity”
`standards in this context. See Hoyt v. Andreucci, 433 F.3d 320, 328 (2d Cir. 2006)
`(noting that “lesser actions may meet the adversity threshold” under what is “a
`heavily fact-specific, contextual determination”).
`
`21
`
`

`

`II.
`
`Causation
`
`We begin with the causation requirement. To show causation, “a plaintiff
`
`must show that the protected speech was a substantial motivating factor in the
`
`adverse employment action.” Smith v. County of Suffolk, 776 F.3d 114, 118 (2d Cir.
`
`2015) (internal quotation marks omitted). Nevertheless, “[b]ecause protected
`
`speech could not substantially cause an adverse action if the employer would
`
`have taken that action in any event, a defendant can rebut a prima facie showing
`
`of retaliation by demonstrating by a preponderance of the evidence that it would
`
`have taken the same adverse employment action even in the absence of the
`
`protected conduct.” Nagle v. Marron, 663 F.3d 100, 111-12 (2d Cir. 2011) (internal
`
`quotation marks omitted), citing Mt. Healthy City Sch. Dist. Bd. of Educ. v. Doyle,
`
`429 U.S. 274, 285-86 (1977) (“The constitutional principle at stake is sufficiently
`
`vindicated if such an employee is placed in no worse a position than if he had not
`
`engaged in the conduct.”).
`
`With those principles in mind, Defendants insist that they “would have
`
`declined to interview plaintiff even in the absence of any hostility to his allegedly
`
`protected speech because he was not qualified for the position.” Appellees’ Br. 25.
`
`The centerpiece of their argument is that Heim lacked any of the qualifications
`
`22
`
`

`

`articulated in Masters’s December 2017 email, which they characterize as: (1) “an
`
`ability to teach and train students in contemporary research techniques”; (2) “a
`
`research agenda that would permit collaboration with the Department’s other
`
`faculty members”; and (3) “a publication record suggesting a strong likelihood of
`
`receiving tenure.” Id. at 15-16.
`
`But any attempt to construe those three requirements as content-neutral
`
`cannot survive even a superficial look at Masters’s actual email. Justifiably or not,
`
`the requirements were soaked in hostility to Keynesianism. At the outset, when
`
`describing the requisite ability to teach and train students in contemporary
`
`research, Masters explicitly defined “modern” as the sort of “post Lucas
`
`Critique[] macroeconomics that by your own admission everyone else but you
`
`and [one other economist] do[es].” App’x 597. In other words, to the Department,
`
`“modern” was antonymous to “Keynesian.” Next, Masters’s explanation for why
`
`Heim’s work was “not consistent” with the collaboration-friendly research
`
`requirement was that the people in the Department Heim would be expected to
`
`collaborate with “do not appreciate” Keynesian research perspectives. Id. at 598.
`
`In fact, the Department had already “rejected” other applicants who “met the
`
`[other] criteria” but “do New Keynesian macro.” Id. Finally, the third job
`
`23
`
`

`

`requirement, setting forth the Department’s publication expectations, is at least
`
`on its face more content-neutral. But even if we take it at face value, the record
`
`suggests that an applicant’s failure to meet the Department’s preferred
`
`publication history standards was not on its own disqualifying. For example, at
`
`the time he was hired, Griffy had also never published (except perhaps as a
`
`research assistant) in the top journals Masters invoked in his email. Nor had Li.
`
`Heim contends, moreover, that Defendants’ “self-reinforcing” assessment of the
`
`“top” journals in the field, id. at 547, is also colored by the fact that those
`
`particular journals “do not publish non-DSGE Keynesian articles,

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket