throbber
Case 1:23-cv-00108 Document 1 Filed 01/24/23 Page 1 of 153 PageID# 1
`
`
`IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
`FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF VIRGINIA
`Alexandria Division
`
`
`UNITED STATES OF AMERICA
`U.S. Department of Justice
`950 Pennsylvania Avenue NW
`Washington, DC 20530
`
`
`COMMONWEALTH OF VIRGINIA
`202 North Ninth Street
`Richmond, VA 23219
`
`
`STATE OF CALIFORNIA
`455 Golden Gate Avenue, Suite 11000
`San Francisco, CA 94102
`
`
`STATE OF COLORADO
`1300 Broadway, 7th Floor
`Denver, CO 80203
`
`
`STATE OF CONNECTICUT
`165 Capitol Avenue
`Hartford, CT 06106
`
`
`STATE OF NEW JERSEY
`124 Halsey Street, 5th Floor
`Newark, NJ 07102
`
`
`STATE OF NEW YORK
`28 Liberty Street, 20th Floor
`New York, NY 10005
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
` JURY TRIAL DEMANDED
`
`
`
`
`
`

`

`Case 1:23-cv-00108 Document 1 Filed 01/24/23 Page 2 of 153 PageID# 2
`
`
`
`
`STATE OF RHODE ISLAND
`150 South Main Street
`Providence, RI 02903
`
`and
`
`STATE OF TENNESSEE
`P.O. Box 20207
`Nashville, TN 37202
`
`Plaintiffs,
`
`v.
`
`GOOGLE LLC
`1600 Amphitheatre Parkway
`Mountain View, CA 94043
`
`Defendant.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`COMPLAINT
`
`
`
`

`

`I.
`II.
`III.
`
`IV.
`
`Case 1:23-cv-00108 Document 1 Filed 01/24/23 Page 3 of 153 PageID# 3
`
`
`
`Table of Contents
`Introduction ......................................................................................................................... 1
`Nature of this Action ........................................................................................................... 4
`Display Advertising Transactions ..................................................................................... 16
`A.
`How Ad Tech Tools Work .................................................................................... 16
`B.
`How Ad Tech Intermediaries Get Paid ................................................................. 22
`C.
`How Publishers and Advertisers Select Ad Tech Tools ....................................... 24
`D. Why Scale and the Resulting Network Effects are Necessary to Compete in
`Ad Tech ................................................................................................................. 26
`How Multi-Homing Enables Competition in the Ad Tech Stack ......................... 28
`E.
`Google’s Scheme to Dominate the Ad Tech Stack ........................................................... 30
`A.
`Google Buys Control of the Key Tools that Link Publishers and Advertisers ..... 31
`B.
`Google Uses Its Acquisitions and Position Across the Ad Tech Stack to Lock
`Out Rivals and Control Each Key Ad Tech Tool ................................................. 35
`1.
`Google Thwarts Fair Competition by Making Its Google Ads’
`Advertiser Demand Exclusive to Its Own Ad Exchange, AdX ................ 37
`In Turn, Google Makes Its Ad Exchange’s Real-Time Bids Exclusive
`to Its Publisher Ad Server ......................................................................... 43
`Finally, Google Uses Its Control of Publisher Inventory to Force More
`Valuable Transactions Through Its Ad Exchange .................................... 46
`Google’s Dominance Across the Ad Tech Stack Gives It the Unique
`Ability to Manipulate Auctions to Protect Its Position, Hinder Rivals,
`and Work Against Its Own Customers’ Interests ..................................... 55
`a)
`Google Works Against the Interests of Its Google Ads’
`Customers By Submitting Two Bids Into AdX Auctions ............. 57
`Google Manipulates Its Fees to Keep More High-Value
`Impressions Out of the Hands of Rivals ....................................... 60
`Google Buys and Kills a Burgeoning Competitor and Then Tightens the
`Screws ................................................................................................................... 65
`1.
`Google Extinguishes AdMeld’s Potential Threat ..................................... 65
`2.
`Google Doubles Down on Preventing Rival Publisher Ad Servers from
`Accessing AdX and Google Ads’ Demand .............................................. 68
`Google Manipulates Google Ads’ Bidding Strategy to Block Publisher
`Partnerships with Rivals ........................................................................... 71
`Google Responds to the Threat of Header Bidding by Further Excluding
`Rivals and Reinforcing Its Dominance ................................................................. 72
`
`2.
`
`3.
`
`4.
`
`b)
`
`C.
`
`D.
`
`3.
`
`i
`
`

`

`Case 1:23-cv-00108 Document 1 Filed 01/24/23 Page 4 of 153 PageID# 4
`
`
`
`1.
`
`2.
`
`b)
`
`c)
`
`The Industry Attempts to Rebel Against Google’s Exclusionary
`Practices .................................................................................................... 72
`Google Blunts Header Bidding By “Drying Out” the Competition ......... 78
`a)
`Google Develops So-Called Open Bidding, Its Own Google-
`Friendly Version of Header Bidding To Preserve Its Control
`Over the Sale of Publisher Inventory ............................................ 78
`Google Further Stunts Header Bidding by Working to Bring
`Facebook and Amazon into Its Open Bidding Fold...................... 82
`Google Manipulates Its Publisher Fees Using Dynamic
`Revenue Sharing in Order to Route More Transactions
`Through Its Ad Exchange and Deny Scale to Rival Ad
`Exchanges Using Header Bidding ................................................ 86
`Google Launches Project Poirot to Manipulate Its Advertisers’
`Spend to “Dry Out” and Deny Scale to Rival Ad Exchanges
`That Use Header Bidding.............................................................. 90
`Google Imposes So-Called Unified Pricing Rules to Deprive
`Publishers of Control and Force More Transactions Through
`Google’s Ad Exchange ............................................................... 101
`Google Outright Blocks the Use of Standard Header Bidding
`on Accelerated Mobile Pages...................................................... 110
`Google Replaces Its Last Look Preference from Dynamic
`Allocation with an Algorithmic Advantage and Degrades Data
`Available to Publishers ............................................................... 113
`Anticompetitive Effects .................................................................................................. 116
`Relevant Markets ............................................................................................................ 123
`A.
`Geographic Markets ............................................................................................ 124
`B.
`Product Markets .................................................................................................. 124
`1.
`Publisher Ad Servers............................................................................... 124
`2.
`Ad Exchanges ......................................................................................... 126
`3.
`Advertiser Ad Networks ......................................................................... 129
`Jurisdiction, Venue, and Commerce ............................................................................... 131
`VII.
`VIII. Violations Alleged .......................................................................................................... 132
`IX.
`Request for Relief ........................................................................................................... 139
`X.
`Demand for a Jury Trial .................................................................................................. 140
`
`d)
`
`e)
`
`f)
`
`g)
`
`V.
`VI.
`
`ii
`
`

`

`Case 1:23-cv-00108 Document 1 Filed 01/24/23 Page 5 of 153 PageID# 5
`
`
`
`I.
`
`INTRODUCTION
`
`1.
`
`An open, vibrant internet is indispensable to American life. But today’s internet
`
`would not exist without the digital advertising revenue that, as a practical matter, funds its
`
`creation and expansion. The internet provides the public with unprecedented access to ideas,
`
`artistic expression, news, commerce, and services. Content creators span every conceivable
`
`industry; they publish diverse material on countless websites that inform, entertain, and connect
`
`society in vital ways. Yet the viability of many of these websites depends on their ability to sell
`
`digital advertising space. Just as newspaper, radio, and television organizations historically relied
`
`on advertising to fund their operations, today’s online publishers likewise rely on advertising
`
`revenue to support their activities and reach. But unlike historical media advertising, today’s
`
`online ads are bought and sold in enormous volumes in mere fractions of a second, using highly
`
`sophisticated tools and automated exchanges that more closely resemble a modern stock
`
`exchange than an old-fashioned, bilateral contract negotiation for newspaper ad space.
`
`2.
`
`Website publishers in the United States sell more than 5 trillion digital display
`
`advertisements on the open web each year—or more than 13 billion advertisements every day.
`
`The sheer volume of these online ads make the offline advertisements of yesteryear pale in
`
`comparison. To put these numbers in perspective, the daily volume of digital display
`
`advertisements grossly outnumbers (by several multiples) the average number of stocks traded
`
`each day on the New York Stock Exchange. The digital display advertising business is also
`
`lucrative. Collectively, these advertisements generate more than $20 billion in revenue per year,
`
`just for publishers based in the United States.
`
`3.
`
`To meet this demand, sophisticated technological tools, informally known as “ad
`
`tech,” have developed to automate advertising matchmaking between two key groups: website
`
`1
`
`

`

`Case 1:23-cv-00108 Document 1 Filed 01/24/23 Page 6 of 153 PageID# 6
`
`
`
`publishers and advertisers.1 These tools have evolved such that today, every time an internet user
`
`opens a webpage with ad space to sell, ad tech tools almost instantly match that website
`
`publisher with an advertiser looking to promote its products or services to the website’s
`
`individual user. This process typically involves the use of an automated advertising exchange
`
`that runs a high-speed auction designed to identify the best match between a publisher selling
`
`internet ad space and the advertisers looking to buy it.
`
`4.
`
`But competition in the ad tech space is broken, for reasons that were neither
`
`accidental nor inevitable. One industry behemoth, Google, has corrupted legitimate competition
`
`in the ad tech industry by engaging in a systematic campaign to seize control of the wide swath
`
`of high-tech tools used by publishers, advertisers, and brokers, to facilitate digital advertising.
`
`Having inserted itself into all aspects of the digital advertising marketplace, Google has used
`
`anticompetitive, exclusionary, and unlawful means to eliminate or severely diminish any threat
`
`to its dominance over digital advertising technologies.
`
`5.
`
`Google’s plan has been simple but effective: (1) neutralize or eliminate ad tech
`
`competitors, actual or potential, through a series of acquisitions; and (2) wield its dominance
`
`across digital advertising markets to force more publishers and advertisers to use its products
`
`while disrupting their ability to use competing products effectively. Whenever Google’s
`
`customers and competitors responded with innovation that threatened Google’s stranglehold over
`
`any one of these ad tech tools, Google’s anticompetitive response has been swift and effective.
`
`Each time a threat has emerged, Google has used its market power in one or more of these ad
`
`
`1 Internet advertisers include businesses, agencies of federal and state governments, charitable
`organizations, political candidates, public interest groups, and more. The money these advertisers
`spend on digital advertising creates an important stream of revenue for websites to use in
`creating, developing, and publishing website content.
`
`2
`
`

`

`Case 1:23-cv-00108 Document 1 Filed 01/24/23 Page 7 of 153 PageID# 7
`
`
`
`tech tools to quash the threat. The result: Google’s plan for durable, industry-wide dominance
`
`has succeeded.
`
`6.
`
`Google, a single company with pervasive conflicts of interest, now controls:
`
`(1) the technology used by nearly every major website publisher to offer advertising space for
`
`sale; (2) the leading tools used by advertisers to buy that advertising space; and (3) the largest ad
`
`exchange that matches publishers with advertisers each time that ad space is sold. Google’s
`
`pervasive power over the entire ad tech industry has been questioned by its own digital
`
`advertising executives, at least one of whom aptly begged the question: “[I]s there a deeper issue
`
`with us owning the platform, the exchange, and a huge network? The analogy would be if
`
`Goldman or Citibank owned the NYSE.”
`
`7.
`
`By deploying opaque rules that benefit itself and harm rivals, Google has wielded
`
`its power across the ad tech industry to dictate how digital advertising is sold, and the very terms
`
`on which its rivals can compete. Google abuses its monopoly power to disadvantage website
`
`publishers and advertisers who dare to use competing ad tech products in a search for higher
`
`quality, or lower cost, matches. Google uses its dominion over digital advertising technology to
`
`funnel more transactions to its own ad tech products where it extracts inflated fees to line its own
`
`pockets at the expense of the advertisers and publishers it purportedly serves.
`
`8.
`
`Google’s anticompetitive behavior has raised barriers to entry to artificially high
`
`levels, forced key competitors to abandon the market for ad tech tools, dissuaded potential
`
`competitors from joining the market, and left Google’s few remaining competitors marginalized
`
`and unfairly disadvantaged. Google has thwarted meaningful competition and deterred
`
`innovation in the digital advertising industry, taken supra-competitive profits for itself, and
`
`3
`
`

`

`Case 1:23-cv-00108 Document 1 Filed 01/24/23 Page 8 of 153 PageID# 8
`
`
`
`prevented the free market from functioning fairly to support the interests of the advertisers and
`
`publishers who make today’s powerful internet possible.
`
`9.
`
`The harm is clear: website creators earn less, and advertisers pay more, than they
`
`would in a market where unfettered competitive pressure could discipline prices and lead to more
`
`innovative ad tech tools that would ultimately result in higher quality and lower cost transactions
`
`for market participants. And this conduct hurts all of us because, as publishers make less money
`
`from advertisements, fewer publishers are able to offer internet content without subscriptions,
`
`paywalls, or alternative forms of monetization. One troubling, but revealing, statistic
`
`demonstrates the point: on average, Google keeps at least thirty cents—and sometimes far
`
`more—of each advertising dollar flowing from advertisers to website publishers through
`
`Google’s ad tech tools. Google’s own internal documents concede that Google would earn far
`
`less in a competitive market.
`
`10.
`
`The United States and Plaintiff States bring this action for violations of the
`
`Sherman Act to halt Google’s anticompetitive scheme, unwind Google’s monopolistic grip on
`
`the market, and restore competition to digital advertising.
`
`II.
`
`NATURE OF THIS ACTION
`
`11.
`
`The seeds for Google’s eventual march toward a monopoly in ad tech were sown
`
`in the early 2000s, when it capitalized on its well-known search engine to start a profitable
`
`search advertising business. In 2000, Google launched Google Ads (then called AdWords2), a
`
`tool that allowed businesses to buy advertisements that could be seen by Google search users
`
`right alongside Google’s popular search engine results. Businesses quickly learned the power of
`
`
`2 Over the period addressed by the Complaint, Google has renamed its ad tech products a number
`of times and has either shifted certain functions between products or combined its products in
`ways intended to obscure Google’s dominance across the ad tech stack.
`
`4
`
`

`

`Case 1:23-cv-00108 Document 1 Filed 01/24/23 Page 9 of 153 PageID# 9
`
`
`
`this instantaneous, highly-targeted advertising technique, and they flocked to Google Ads as a
`
`result.
`
`12.
`
`By the early 2000s, Google realized that these same advertisers would buy digital
`
`advertisements on third-party websites as well. So Google stepped in to profit (as a middleman)
`
`on digital advertising transactions having nothing to do with Google or its search engine by
`
`creating an advertiser ad tech tool for Google Ads’ customers that wanted to buy ad space on
`
`third-party websites.
`
`13.
`
`But Google was not satisfied with its dominance on the advertising side of the
`
`industry alone; Google devised a plan to build a moat around the emerging ad tech industry by
`
`developing a tool that would be used by website publishers as well.
`
`14.
`
`Google sought to develop an ad tech tool called a publisher ad server that
`
`publishers would use to manage their online advertising sales. Google recognized that because
`
`publisher ad servers set the rules for how and to whom publisher advertising opportunities are
`
`sold, owning a publisher ad server was key to having visibility into, and control over, the
`
`publisher side of digital advertising. By controlling the publisher ad server on the other end of
`
`the transaction, Google could further entrench its advertiser customer base by giving advertisers
`
`access to more advertising opportunities and pushing more transactions their way.
`
`15.
`
`Of course, by becoming the dominant player on both sides of the digital
`
`advertising industry, Google could also play both sides against the middle. It could control both
`
`the publishers with digital ad space to sell, as well as the advertisers who want to buy that space.
`
`With influence over advertising transactions end-to-end, Google realized it could become “the
`
`be-all, and end-all location for all ad serving.” The outsized influence it could obtain by having a
`
`dominant position on both sides of the industry would give Google the ability to charge supra-
`
`5
`
`

`

`Case 1:23-cv-00108 Document 1 Filed 01/24/23 Page 10 of 153 PageID# 10
`
`
`
`competitive fees and also enjoy an abiding dominance sufficient to exclude rivals from
`
`competition. Google would no longer have to compete on the merits; it could simply set the rules
`
`of the game to exclude rivals.
`
`16.
`
`The only problem with Google’s plan was that Google’s publisher ad server failed
`
`to gain traction in the industry. So, Google pivoted to acquiring the market-leading publisher ad
`
`server from an ad tech firm called DoubleClick. In early 2008, Google closed its acquisition of
`
`DoubleClick for over $3 billion. Through the transaction, Google acquired a publisher ad server
`
`(“DoubleClick for Publishers” or “DFP”), which had a 60% market share at the time. It also
`
`acquired a nascent ad exchange (“AdX”) through which digital advertising space could be
`
`auctioned. The DoubleClick acquisition vaulted Google into a commanding position over the
`
`tools publishers use to sell advertising opportunities, complementing Google’s existing tool for
`
`advertisers, Google Ads, and set the stage for Google’s later exclusionary conduct across the ad
`
`tech industry.
`
`17.
`
`After the DoubleClick acquisition, Google enhanced and entrenched DFP’s
`
`already-dominant market position. Google internally recognized that publisher ad servers are
`
`“sticky” products, meaning that publishers rarely switch because of the high costs and risks
`
`involved. As DoubleClick’s former CEO observed, “Nothing has such high switching costs. . . .
`
`Takes an act of God to do it.” Thus, in order to lock more publishers into DFP and to reinforce
`
`its stickiness, Google forged an exclusive link between Google Ads and DFP through the AdX
`
`ad exchange. If publishers wanted access to exclusive Google Ads’ advertising demand, they had
`
`to use Google’s publisher ad server (DFP) and ad exchange (AdX), rather than equivalent tools
`
`offered by Google’s rivals. In effect, Google positioned itself to function simultaneously as
`
`buyer, seller, and auctioneer of digital display advertising.
`
`6
`
`

`

`Case 1:23-cv-00108 Document 1 Filed 01/24/23 Page 11 of 153 PageID# 11
`
`
`
`18.
`
`Google’s strategy paid off. This arrangement has had a profound effect on the
`
`evolution of digital advertising. First, it tilted the industry in Google’s favor, driving publishers
`
`to adopt and stay on Google’s DFP publisher ad server in order to have access to Google Ads’
`
`advertiser demand. Second, it cut off the possibility that Google Ads’ advertiser spending could
`
`sustain, or encourage the entry of, a rival ad exchange or publisher ad server by providing critical
`
`advertising demand. For the vast majority of webpage publishers, this arrangement made DFP
`
`the only realistic publisher ad server option. Indeed, by 2015, Google estimated that DFP’s
`
`publisher ad server market share had grown to a remarkable 90%. Google’s durable monopoly
`
`over the publisher ad server market has allowed it to avoid innovation and competition by
`
`controlling the very rules by which the game is played. As a result, other publisher ad servers
`
`have left the market altogether, refocused on related markets, or faded into insignificance; no
`
`new publisher ad servers have entered the market.
`
`19.
`
`Around the same time that Google tied its exclusive Google Ads’ advertiser
`
`demand to its publisher ad server (DFP) through AdX, Google took two additional steps to make
`
`it more difficult for rivals to compete.
`
`20.
`
`First, Google configured Google Ads to bid on Google’s AdX ad exchange in a
`
`way that actually increased the price of advertising, to the benefit of publishers and the detriment
`
`of Google’s own advertiser customers. As one Google employee observed, Google Ads was
`
`effectively sending a “$3bn yearly check [to publishers] by overcharging our advertisers to
`
`ensure we’re strong on the pub[lisher] side.” In the short-term, this conduct locked publishers
`
`into Google’s publisher ad server by providing them a steady stream of intentionally-inflated
`
`prices for certain inventory, at the cost of Google’s own advertiser customers. But in the long
`
`run, Google’s actions harmed publishers as well by driving out rival publisher ad servers and
`
`7
`
`

`

`Case 1:23-cv-00108 Document 1 Filed 01/24/23 Page 12 of 153 PageID# 12
`
`
`
`limiting competition in the publisher ad server market. In effect, Google was robbing from Peter
`
`(the advertisers) to pay Paul (the publishers), all the while collecting a hefty transaction fee for
`
`its own privileged position in the middle. This conduct turned the entire purpose of the digital
`
`advertising industry on its head. Rather than helping to fund website publishing, Google was
`
`siphoning off advertising dollars for itself through the imposition of supra-competitive fees on its
`
`platforms. A rival publisher ad server could not compete with Google’s inflated ad prices,
`
`especially without access to Google’s captive advertiser demand from Google Ads.
`
`21.
`
`Second, Google used its captive advertiser demand to thwart legitimate
`
`competition by giving its AdX ad exchange an advantage over other ad exchanges through a
`
`mechanism known as dynamic allocation. Dynamic allocation was a means by which Google
`
`manipulated its publisher ad server to give the Google-owned AdX (and only AdX) the
`
`opportunity to buy publisher inventory before it was offered to any other ad exchange, and often
`
`to do so at artificially low prices. Google also programmed DFP, its publisher ad server, to
`
`prevent publishers from offering preferential terms to other ad exchanges or allowing those
`
`exchanges to operate in the same way with DFP. Google knew that dynamic allocation would
`
`inevitably steer advertising transactions away from rivals, denying them critical scale needed to
`
`compete, and would advantage AdX, where Google could extract the largest fees. Google’s
`
`scheme predictably reinforced publishers’ dependence on both AdX and DFP. Publishers were
`
`effectively precluded from using rival ad servers or ad exchanges that might better suit their
`
`needs while Google was given a free pass from having to compete on the merits with those
`
`rivals.
`
`22.
`
`By at least 2010, other ad tech companies had recognized that Google’s platforms
`
`were not working in the best interest of publishers, and they attempted to develop innovative
`
`8
`
`

`

`Case 1:23-cv-00108 Document 1 Filed 01/24/23 Page 13 of 153 PageID# 13
`
`
`
`technologies to introduce more competition. Some companies began offering “yield
`
`management” functionality that helped publishers identify on a real-time basis better prices for
`
`their inventory outside of Google’s products. Google recognized that yield managers posed a
`
`major threat to the increasingly closed system Google sought to establish, in which only its ad
`
`exchange was able to compete based on real-time pricing. So, in response, Google employed a
`
`familiar tactic: acquire, then extinguish, any competitive threat.
`
`23.
`
`In 2011, Google acquired AdMeld, the leading yield manager, folded its
`
`functionality into Google’s existing products, and then shut down its operations with non-Google
`
`ad exchanges and advertiser tools. Google soon thereafter changed its AdX contract terms to
`
`prohibit publishers from using any other platform (such as another yield manager) that would
`
`force AdX to compete in real time with other ad exchanges. As a Google product manager wrote:
`
`“Our goal should be all or nothing – use AdX as your [exchange] or don’t get access to our
`
`[advertising] demand.” Unsurprisingly, this unabashed, anticompetitive conduct had a profound
`
`effect on the market, denying rival ad tech competitors the scale necessary to compete and
`
`depriving publishers the benefits of free market competition and real choice.
`
`24.
`
`Not long after, in 2013, Google launched Project Bernanke, a secret scheme to
`
`manipulate the bids that Google Ads submitted into Google’s ad exchange, AdX, in order to win
`
`more competitive transactions and solidify AdX’s dominance in the industry. Project Bernanke
`
`allowed Google to suppress competition by preventing rival ad exchanges from achieving the
`
`transaction volume and scale necessary to compete. Unless another ad exchange developed both
`
`its own unique source of captive advertiser demand—where it could potentially manipulate
`
`advertiser bids—and a widely-adopted publisher ad server—where it could see the same
`
`advertising inventory and bid data as Google—competition on the same terms as Google was
`
`9
`
`

`

`Case 1:23-cv-00108 Document 1 Filed 01/24/23 Page 14 of 153 PageID# 14
`
`
`
`nearly impossible. Once again, by controlling all sides of the ad tech industry, Google has been
`
`able to manipulate the system in ways unique to itself so that, in the end, it did not have to
`
`compete on the merits for customers and volume.
`
`25.
`
`Publishers and competing ad tech providers, increasingly wary of Google’s
`
`bullying behavior, have continued to look for new ways to circumvent Google’s dominance.
`
`Between 2012 and 2013, market participants began using a technique called “header bidding”
`
`as a partial workaround to Google’s self-preferential algorithms and ad tech restrictions. As one
`
`Google employee explained, “Publishers felt locked-in by dynamic allocation in [Google’s ad
`
`server] which only gave [Google’s ad exchange] the ability to compete, so HB [header bidding]
`
`was born.”
`
`26.
`
`Publishers used header bidding to take back some degree of power over their own
`
`advertising transactions. They inserted header bidding computer code onto their own websites to
`
`allow non-Google advertising exchanges an opportunity to bid for advertising inventory before
`
`Google’s hard-coded preferences for its own ad exchange were triggered. Header bidding
`
`allowed publishers to ensure that multiple advertising exchanges—not just Google’s AdX—
`
`could bid on their inventory, thereby increasing the chances that they could find the best match.
`
`27.
`
`Google has refused to tolerate this new form of competition, even though it has
`
`acknowledged in internal emails that header bidding had grown naturally out of Google’s being
`
`“unwilling[] to open our systems to the types of transactions, policies and innovations that
`
`buyers and sellers wish to transact.” Indeed, Google privately admitted that “header bidding and
`
`header wrappers are BETTER than [Google’s platforms] for buyers and sellers,” and that
`
`increased competition between AdX and publishers using header bidding would increase
`
`publisher revenues by 30 to 40%, and would provide additional transparency to advertisers. Not
`
`10
`
`

`

`Case 1:23-cv-00108 Document 1 Filed 01/24/23 Page 15 of 153 PageID# 15
`
`
`
`only would header bidding enable rival exchanges to compete more effectively against Google’s
`
`ad exchange, it might also allow them or others to enter the publisher ad server market if Google
`
`no longer had exclusive access to unique advertiser demand.
`
`28.
`
`Google executives described header bidding as an “existential threat.” They
`
`worried that wider adoption of header bidding practices could lead to Google’s ad exchange
`
`having to compete with other ad exchanges on a level playing field, where Google could no
`
`longer set the rules in its own favor. If that were to happen, those rival ad exchanges might
`
`actually succeed in eroding, or even breaking up, Google’s advertiser juggernaut, and the entire
`
`industry could be opened up for competition. Google feared the worst: the entire moat of
`
`anticompetitive protections that Google had built around the ad tech industry could be breached.
`
`29.
`
`Faced with this “existential” threat, Google sought to stem the rising tide toward
`
`header bidding by promoting a Google-friendly analog of header bidding that Google
`
`deceptively titled “Open Bidding.” Google has promoted Open Bidding as an answer to the
`
`industry’s call for wider participation by rival ad exchanges and increased competition. In fact,
`
`Open Bidding was a Trojan Horse that Google used to further cement its own monopoly power.
`
`30.
`
`As a condition to using Google’s Open Bidding, Google has required that
`
`publishers and participating ad exchanges give Google visibility into each auction (including
`
`how rival exchanges bid), allow Google to extract a sizeable fee on every transaction (even
`
`where another exchange won), and limit the pool of advertisers allowed to bid in the auctions. In
`
`doing so, Google’s ad exchange has retained a guaranteed seat in every auction, regardless of
`
`whether Google’s ad exchange offers the best match between advertisers and publishers.
`
`31.
`
`Google also sought to co-opt what it perceived to be its two biggest threats
`
`(Facebook and Amazon) into Open Bidding. In internal documents, Google concluded that while
`
`11
`
`

`

`Case 1:23-cv-00108 Document 1 Filed 01/24/23 Page 16 of 153 PageID# 16
`
`
`
`it “[c]annot avoid competing with FAN [Facebook],” it could, through a deal with Facebook,
`
`“build a moat around our demand.” Internal documents recommending a deal with Facebook
`
`revealed Google’s primary motive: “[f]or web inventory, we will move [Facebook’s] demand off
`
`of header bidding set up and further weaken the header bidding narrative in the marketplace.”
`
`Thus, for these reasons, Google ultimately agreed to provide preferential Open Bidding auction
`
`terms to Facebook in exchange for spend and pricing commitments designed to push more of
`
`Facebook’s captive advertiser spend onto Google’s platforms. Google sought to head off
`
`Amazon’s investment in header bidding technology with a similar offer, albeit without the same
`
`success.
`
`32.
`
`Google also adjusted its auction mechanisms across its ad tech products to divert
`
`more transactions to itself and away from rivals that might deploy header bidding. On the
`
`publisher side, Google allowed AdX—and only AdX—to change its auction bid by altering
`
`Google’s own fee after seeing the price to beat from another exchange.
`
`33.
`
`On the advertiser side, Google first considered outright blocking its advertiser
`
`buying tool from buying inventory made available via header bidding. The goal: “dry out HB
`
`[header bidding].” When Google decided that strategy would be too costly for Google, it pivoted
`
`to a different and more insidious

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket