throbber
Case: 21-16506, 01/27/2022, ID: 12353961, DktEntry: 57, Page 1 of 39
`
`Nos. 21-16506 & 21-16695
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`IN THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
`FOR THE NINTH CIRCUIT
`____________________
`EPIC GAMES, INC.,
`Plaintiff, Counter-Defendant–Appellant, Cross-Appellee
`v.
`APPLE, INC.,
`Defendant, Counterclaimant–Appellee, Cross-Appellant
`____________________
`On Appeal from the United States District Court
`for the Northern District of California
`No. 4:20-cv-05640-YGR-TSH
`The Honorable Yvonne Gonzalez Rogers
`
` ____________________
`BRIEF OF THE AMERICAN ANTITRUST INSTITUTE AS AMICUS
`CURIAE IN SUPPORT OF PLAINTIFF, COUNTER-DEFENDANT–
`APPELLANT
`____________________
`
`
`LAURA M. ALEXANDER
`
`
` Counsel of Record
`
`
`RANDY M. STUTZ
`AMERICAN ANTITRUST INSTITUTE
`1025 Connecticut Avenue, NW
`Suite 1000
`
`Washington, DC 20036
`
`
`(202) 276-4050
`
`lalexander@antitrustinstitute.org
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`January 27, 2022
`
`Counsel for Amicus Curiae
`
`

`

`Case: 21-16506, 01/27/2022, ID: 12353961, DktEntry: 57, Page 2 of 39
`
`
`
`CORPORATE DISCLOSURE STATEMENT
`
`Pursuant to Appellate Rule 26.1(a), the American Antitrust Institute states
`
`that it is a nonprofit, non-stock corporation. It has no parent corporations, and no
`
`publicly traded corporations have an ownership interest in it.
`
`
`
`
`
`
`
`i
`
`

`

`Case: 21-16506, 01/27/2022, ID: 12353961, DktEntry: 57, Page 3 of 39
`
`
`
`
`CORPORATE DISCLOSURE STATEMENT ..................................................... i
`
`TABLE OF CONTENTS
`
`TABLE OF AUTHORITIES ................................................................................ iii
`
`INTEREST OF AMICUS CURIAE ...................................................................... 1
`
`INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY OF ARGUMENT ................................... 2
`
`ARGUMENT ........................................................................................................... 5
`
`I. COURTS MUST DEFINE MARKETS CONSISTENT
`WITH FIRST PRINCIPLES OF ANTITRUST LAW ............................. 5
`
`A. The District Court’s Opinion Cannot be Squared with
`First Principles of Antitrust Law Reflected in Kodak .......................... 5
`
`B. The District Court Did Not Properly Assess Apple’s Conduct
`as It Relates to the Source of Apple’s Market Power ........................ 10
`
`C. A Common Error Underlies the District Court’s Failure to
`Recognize Distinct Markets in at Least Two Instances ..................... 14
`
`D. AmEx Applies Only to the Narrow Economic Circumstances
`that Underly Its Departure from Well-established Market
`Definition Principles .............................................................................. 21
`
`II. UPHOLDING THE DECISION BELOW WOULD PROVIDE
`A ROADMAP FOR PLATFORMS TO EVADE FEDERAL
`ANTITRUST LAWS WITH ENORMOUS IMPLICATIONS
`FOR CONSUMERS, DEVELOPERS, AND MARKETS ...................... 29
`
`CONCLUSION ..................................................................................................... 31
`
`
`
`ii
`
`

`

`Case: 21-16506, 01/27/2022, ID: 12353961, DktEntry: 57, Page 4 of 39
`
`
`
`
`
`CASES
`
`
`
`TABLE OF AUTHORITIES
`
`
`American Needle, Inc. v. National Football League,
`560 U.S. 183 (2010) .............................................................................................. 3
`
`Apple, Inc. v. Pepper,
`139 S.Ct. 1514 (2019) ......................................................................................... 29
`
`Digidyne Corp. v. Data Gen. Corp.,
`734 F.2d 1336 (9th Cir. 1984) ............................................................................. 19
`
`Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Tech. Servs.,
`540 U.S. 451 (1992) ..................................................................................... passim
`
`Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Tech. Servs.,
`903 F.2d 612 (9th Cir. 1990) ............................................................................... 19
`
`Image Tech. Servs. v. Eastman Kodak Co.,
`125 F.3d 1195 (9th Cir. 1997) ............................................................................. 11
`
`Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde,
`466 U.S. 2 (1984) ...................................................................................... 2, 17, 19
`
`Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc.,
`551 U.S. 877 (2007) ............................................................................................ 23
`
`Nat’l Soc’y of Prof’l Eng’rs v. United States,
`435 U.S. 679 (1978) .............................................................................................. 2
`
`Newcal Industries, Inc. v. IKON Office Solutions,
`513 F.3d 1038 (9th Cir. 2008) ............................................................................... 8
`
`Ohio v. American Express,
`138 S. Ct. 2274 (2018) ................................................................................. passim
`
`Rick-Mik Enters., Inc. v. Equilon Enters. LLC,
`532 F.3d 963 (9th Cir. 2008) ......................................................................... 17, 18
`
`
`
`iii
`
`

`

`Case: 21-16506, 01/27/2022, ID: 12353961, DktEntry: 57, Page 5 of 39
`
`
`
`Times-Picayune Publishing Co. v. United States,
`345 U.S. 594 (1953) ...................................................................................... 11, 25
`
`United States v. Microsoft Corp.,
`253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001) (en banc) .............................................................. 19
`
`United States v. Sabre Corp.,
`452 F. Supp. 3d 97 (D. Del. 2020) ...................................................................... 24
`
`OTHER AUTHORITIES
`
`Brief for Petitioner Apple, Apple, Inc. v. Pepper, No. 17-204,
`139 S. Ct. 1514 (filed Aug. 10, 2018) ..................................................... 26, 27, 28
`
`Daniel J. Solove, The Myth of the Privacy Paradox,
`89 GEO. WASH. L. REV. 1 (Jan. 2021) ................................................................. 30
`
`Dennis W. Carlton, The Anticompetitive Effects of Vertical
`Most-Favored-Nation Restraints and the Error of Amex,
`2019 Columbia Bus. L. Rev. 93 (2019) ........................................................ 22, 24
`
`Donald Turner, Antitrust Policy and the Cellophane Case,
`70 Harv. L. Rev. 281 (1956) ............................................................................... 16
`
`Fed. Trade Comm’n & U.S. Dep’t of Just.,
`Antitrust Div., Horizontal Merger Guidelines (2010) ................................... 16, 28
`
`Federal Trade Comm’n & U.S. Dep’t of Justice,
`Commentary on the Horizontal Merger Guidelines (2006) ................................ 28
`
`Herbert Hovenkamp, Platforms and the Rule of Reason:
`The American Express Case, 2019 COLUMBIA BUS. L. REV. 35 (2019) ............. 22
`
`Jack Kirkwood, Antitrust and Two-Sided Platforms:
`The Failure of American Express, 41 CARDOZO L. REV. 1805 (2020) ............... 22
`
`Jeffrey Harrison, Ohio v. American Express: Misunderstanding
`Two-Sided Platforms; the Charge Card “Market;” and the Need for
`Procompetitive Justifications, 70 MERCER L. REV. 437 (2019) .......................... 22
`
`
`
`iv
`
`

`

`Case: 21-16506, 01/27/2022, ID: 12353961, DktEntry: 57, Page 6 of 39
`
`
`
`Lapo Filistrucchi et al., Market Definition in Two-Sided Markets:
`Theory and Practice, 10 J. Comp. L. & Econ. 293 (2014) ................................. 28
`
`Michael Katz & Jonathan Sallet, Multisided Platforms
`and Antitrust Enforcement, 127 YALE L.J. 2142 (2018) ......................... 22, 24, 25
`
`Michael L. Katz & A. Douglas Melamed, Competition Law
`as Common Law: American Express and the Evolution of Antitrust,
`168 U. PENN. L. REV. 2061 (2000) ................................................................ 22, 23
`
`Steven C. Salop et al., Rebuilding Platform Antitrust: Moving on from
`Ohio v. American Express (forthcoming), .................................................... 22, 24
`
`Steven C. Salop, The First Principles Approach to Antitrust, Kodak,
`and Antitrust at the Millennium, 68 ANTITRUST L.J. 187 (2000) .......... 2, 3, 13, 16
`
`TREATISES
`
`Carl Shapiro & Hal R. Varian, Information Rules: A Strategic Guide to the
`Network Economy (1999) ................................................................................... 29
`
`Phillip Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp,
`Antitrust Law (4th and 5th eds. 2013-2020) ..................................... 14, 17, 19, 20
`
`
`
`v
`
`

`

`Case: 21-16506, 01/27/2022, ID: 12353961, DktEntry: 57, Page 7 of 39
`
`
`
`INTEREST OF AMICUS CURIAE1
`The American Antitrust Institute (“AAI”) is an independent nonprofit organ-
`
`ization devoted to promoting competition that protects consumers, businesses, and
`
`society. It serves the public through research, education, and advocacy on the ben-
`
`efits of competition and the use of antitrust enforcement as a vital component of
`
`national and international competition policy. AAI enjoys the input of an Advisory
`
`Board that consists of over 130 prominent antitrust lawyers, law professors, econo-
`
`mists, and business leaders. See http://www.antitrustinstitute.org.2
`
`
`
`
`
`
`1 The parties have lodged blanket consents with the clerk. No counsel for a party
`has authored this brief in whole or in part, and no party, party’s counsel, or any
`other person—other than amicus curiae or its counsel—has contributed money that
`was intended to fund preparing or submitting this brief.
`2 Individual views of members of AAI’s Board of Directors or Advisory Board
`may differ from AAI’s positions.
`
`
`
`1
`
`

`

`Case: 21-16506, 01/27/2022, ID: 12353961, DktEntry: 57, Page 8 of 39
`
`
`
`INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY OF ARGUMENT
`
`Despite radical technological and business innovation over the last century,
`
`the Sherman Act remains as relevant to markets today as ever. Moreover, while
`
`the Act’s application has evolved with these developments, the core legal and eco-
`
`nomic principles underlying the Sherman Act have remained remarkably constant.
`
`For good reason: faithful adherence to these first principles of antitrust law means
`
`“courts can maintain logic and consistency while avoiding analytic traps and fac-
`
`tual errors.” Steven C. Salop, The First Principles Approach to Antitrust, Kodak,
`
`and Antitrust at the Millennium, 68 Antitrust L.J. 187, 3 (2000) (hereinafter
`
`“Salop”).
`
`Central among them are the legislative judgment that consumers and society
`
`are best served by competitive markets and that the ultimate test under any antitrust
`
`analysis should be the effect of the defendant’s conduct on competition. Nat’l
`
`Soc’y of Prof’l Eng’rs v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 695 (1978); see also Jeffer-
`
`son Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2, 12 (1984).
`
`Antitrust law has also steadfastly emphasized the need to confront markets
`
`as they are and to eschew formalism in favor of market realities. Eastman Kodak
`
`Co. v. Image Tech. Servs., 540 U.S. 451, 462 (1992) (“Legal presumptions that rest
`
`on formalistic distinctions rather than actual market realities are generally disfa-
`
`vored in antitrust law.”); see also American Needle, Inc. v. Nat’l Football League,
`
`
`
`2
`
`

`

`Case: 21-16506, 01/27/2022, ID: 12353961, DktEntry: 57, Page 9 of 39
`
`
`
`560 U.S. 183, 191 (2010) (modern antitrust law “eschew[s]…formalistic distinc-
`
`tions…in favor of a functional consideration of how the parties involved in the al-
`
`leged anticompetitive conduct actually operate”). Where the anticompetitive
`
`impact of conduct is readily apparent, tests and proxies must yield to the directly
`
`observable market realities. Salop at 4 (“Market definition and market power
`
`should be evaluated in the context of the alleged anticompetitive conduct and ef-
`
`fect, not as a flawed filter carried out in a vacuum divorced from these factors.”).
`
`This case provides a prime example of the pitfalls that come with applying
`
`multi-pronged tests and proxies without tying them back to first principles or tak-
`
`ing account of “the context of the alleged anticompetitive conduct and effect.”
`
`Salop at 191. The district court found direct anticompetitive effects from Apple’s
`
`conduct yet held that Apple lacks market power. Its legal conclusion cannot fol-
`
`low from its finding of fact. The analysis is economically incoherent.
`
` The district court failed to appreciate the significance of its finding of direct
`
`anticompetitive effects. Fundamentally, courts must define markets “in reference
`
`to the economic analysis of the alleged anticompetitive conduct and its market ef-
`
`fect.” Id. Here, the court failed to do that in at least three ways:
`
`First, despite factual findings that directly evidence iPhone purchasers are
`
`locked-in by both information costs that prevent accurate lifecycle pricing and
`
`switching costs that weigh against switching from iOS to Android to access
`
`
`
`3
`
`

`

`Case: 21-16506, 01/27/2022, ID: 12353961, DktEntry: 57, Page 10 of 39
`
`
`
`alternative app-distribution services and in-app payment processors, the district
`
`court held there could be no relevant aftermarkets in Apple app-distribution and in-
`
`app payment processing. Had the district court properly understood the economic
`
`and legal significance of its factual findings in the context of Apple’s alleged anti-
`
`competitive conduct and its effects, it could not have arrived at this result.
`
`Second, in defining markets, the district court at least twice fell into the ana-
`
`lytical trap of assuming that current, competitively-constrained market conditions
`
`reflect the contours of consumer demand. In at least two instances, it found a sin-
`
`gle product where, had it properly focused on consumer demand in the context of
`
`Epic’s claims, it would have found two. As a result, it failed to credit plaintiffs’
`
`foremarket in mobile operating systems and mistook the results of Apple’s leverag-
`
`ing as evidence that no leveraging was possible.
`
`Third, the district court applied the Amex decision without attention to the
`
`economic justifications for that decision’s limited application and narrow scope.
`
`As a result, the district court treated one-sided app distribution and in-app payment
`
`markets as transaction services markets, despite the fact that, by Apple’s own
`
`
`
`4
`
`

`

`Case: 21-16506, 01/27/2022, ID: 12353961, DktEntry: 57, Page 11 of 39
`
`
`
`admission, it does not sell app-distribution services and in-app payment services to
`
`consumers and these services are not jointly consumed.
`
`ARGUMENT
`
`I.
`
`COURTS MUST DEFINE MARKETS CONSISTENT WITH FIRST
`PRINCIPLES OF ANTITRUST LAW
`
`Legal tests and frameworks developed in the context of tangible goods can
`
`be difficult to apply in new and evolving digital markets. But such tests are only a
`
`proxy for the ultimate goal of any antitrust inquiry: to determine the impact of
`
`conduct on competition. Courts can correctly apply old tests to new contexts only
`
`by adhering to the first principles underlying this ultimate goal.
`
`A.
`
`The District Court’s Opinion Cannot be Squared with First Prin-
`ciples of Antitrust Law Reflected in Kodak
`
`The district court correctly identified the issue at the heart of Epic’s after-
`
`market monopolization argument: “whether competition in the initial market [for
`
`operating systems] suffices to discipline anticompetitive practices in the aftermar-
`
`kets” for iOS in-app payments and iOS app distribution. Slip op. at 130; see Ko-
`
`dak, 504 U.S. at 469 n.15 (“Whether considered in the conceptual category of
`
`‘market definition’ or ‘market power,’ the ultimate inquiry is the same—whether
`
`competition in the equipment market will significantly restrain power in the service
`
`and parts markets.”). And, the court rightly recognized that “[i]ssues of lock-in or
`
`switching costs, and notice or consumer knowledge fall under th[is] analysis.” Id.
`
`
`
`5
`
`

`

`Case: 21-16506, 01/27/2022, ID: 12353961, DktEntry: 57, Page 12 of 39
`
`
`
`But the district court abandoned first principles by failing to connect its assessment
`
`of switching and information costs to the ultimate competition issue Epic has
`
`raised.
`
`In Kodak, the plaintiffs alleged that Kodak had market power in replacement
`
`parts for Kodak copiers and used that market power to unlawfully tie Kodak parts
`
`to Kodak repair services. Id. at 459. Kodak’s near-100% market share in replace-
`
`ment parts for Kodak copiers was undisputed; the question was whether Kodak ac-
`
`tually possessed market power over parts purchases. Kodak argued, as Apple did
`
`here, that it had no meaningful market power in the Kodak parts market, because if
`
`it tried to charge supracompetitive prices or impose anticompetitive terms on parts
`
`purchases, customers would either switch to a different brand of copier or would
`
`avoid buying Kodak copiers in the first place. On summary judgment, the Su-
`
`preme Court disagreed, explaining that the theory was “perhaps intuitively appeal-
`
`ing [but] may not accurately explain the behavior of the primary and derivative
`
`markets for complex durable goods.” Id. at 473.
`
`“The extent to which one market prevents exploitation of another market,”
`
`the Court reasoned, “depends on the extent to which consumers will change their
`
`consumption of one product in response to a price change in another, i.e., the
`
`cross-elasticity of demand.” Id. at 469 (internal quotations omitted). Where con-
`
`sumers in the aftermarket can readily change their consumption in the foremarket
`
`
`
`6
`
`

`

`Case: 21-16506, 01/27/2022, ID: 12353961, DktEntry: 57, Page 13 of 39
`
`
`
`in response to exploitation in the aftermarket, there is no market power. Where
`
`consumers subject to exploitation in the aftermarket cannot readily avoid or change
`
`their consumption in the foremarket in response, they are “locked-in.”
`
`The Court recognized that this lock-in is a source of the market power in the
`
`aftermarket, even if the lock-in is not complete. Id. at 471 (“The fact that the
`
`[fore]market imposes a restraint on prices in the after-markets by no means dis-
`
`proves the existence of power in those markets.”). Consequently, a finding of
`
`lock-in and market power in this context necessarily suggests that the aftermarket
`
`is a relevant antitrust market. Id. at 469 n.15 (“Whether considered in the concep-
`
`tual category of ‘market definition’ or ‘market power,’ the ultimate inquiry is the
`
`same—whether competition in the equipment market will significantly restrain
`
`power in the service and parts markets.”) (emphasis added).
`
`The Supreme Court identified two causal factors that can generate lock-in:
`
`information costs and switching costs. Id. at 473. Information costs prevent
`
`“lifecycle pricing.” Id. High information costs matter because consumers who
`
`cannot readily assess the full lifecycle costs when they purchase a product cannot
`
`account for those costs when making their initial purchasing decision. Id. Switch-
`
`ing costs prevent switching to a different product after the initial purchasing deci-
`
`sion. High switching costs matter because consumers who cannot easily switch
`
`
`
`7
`
`

`

`Case: 21-16506, 01/27/2022, ID: 12353961, DktEntry: 57, Page 14 of 39
`
`
`
`products in the foremarket cannot escape the exercise of market power in the after-
`
`market.
`
`Information costs lead consumers into a vulnerable position, and switching
`
`costs keeps them there. Together, they generate a relevant antitrust market: an af-
`
`termarket where consumers are locked-in. Absent competition in the aftermarket,
`
`market power can be exercised in the aftermarket with anticompetitive effect.
`
`Here, the district court found that both switching costs and information costs
`
`were present,3 yet found no aftermarket for iOS app distribution or in-app payment.
`
`Again, the legal conclusion does not coherently follow from the fact-finding. To
`
`find such switching and information costs without finding an aftermarket is funda-
`
`mentally incompatible with the market definition principles underlying Kodak and
`
`Newcal Industries, Inc. v. IKON Office Solutions, 513 F.3d 1038 (9th Cir. 2008).
`
`The presence of these information and switching costs necessarily suggests that
`
`competition in the foremarket will not “significantly restrain” market power in the
`
`aftermarket. Kodak, 504 U.S. at 469 n.15.
`
`
`3 The district court found switching costs when it held: “The Court can agree that it
`takes time to find and reinstall apps or find substitute apps; to learn a new operat-
`ing system; and to reconfigure app settings. It is further apparent that one may
`need to repurchase phone accessories.” Slip op. at 50. It found information costs
`when it held: “Apple’s anti-steering provisions hid critical information from con-
`sumers,” Slip op. at 2, and that “Apple used other provisions to hide information
`on those commission rates from the consumers…. Without information, consum-
`ers cannot have a full understanding of the costs.” Slip op. at 50-51.
`
`
`
`8
`
`

`

`Case: 21-16506, 01/27/2022, ID: 12353961, DktEntry: 57, Page 15 of 39
`
`
`
`Moreover, the district court is wrong to assert that the popularity of Apple’s
`
`products reduces the magnitude of switching costs. Slip op. at 51 (“evidence
`
`strongly suggests that low switching between operating systems stems from overall
`
`satisfaction with existing devices, rather any [sic] ‘lock-in’”). To be sure, demand
`
`for Apple’s devices and operating system has significant implications for competi-
`
`tion in the markets for devices and operating systems. But the only relevant ques-
`
`tion here is whether that foremarket competition disciplines the aftermarkets. If it
`
`does not, the foremarket competition says nothing about market power in the after-
`
`markets.
`
`Similarly, the district court is wrong to assert that consumer knowledge that
`
`the iPhone is a walled garden reduces the magnitude of information costs. Slip op.
`
`at 131 (“In short, there is no evidence in the record demonstrating that consumers
`
`are unaware that the App Store is the sole means of digital distribution on the iOS
`
`platform.”). The only relevant question is whether customers have a way to assess
`
`the costs of Apple’s walled-garden approach at the time they purchase an iPhone.
`
`It is consumers’ inability to assess Apple’s aftermarket pricing constraints at the
`
`time of purchase that generates the information costs and prevents foremarket com-
`
`petition from disciplining aftermarket conduct.
`
`The district court held that streaming services and cross-platform gaming
`
`have also reduced switching costs, Slip op. at 131, but again the court cannot
`
`
`
`9
`
`

`

`Case: 21-16506, 01/27/2022, ID: 12353961, DktEntry: 57, Page 16 of 39
`
`
`
`connect its dots. This holding is fundamentally incompatible with its holding that
`
`these services are not included in the mobile gaming market. Slip op. at 85. When
`
`the district court found that streaming services and cross-platform gaming are not
`
`part of the relevant market in this case, it necessarily found that switching between
`
`mobile gaming and these products is not sufficient to constrain prices in mobile
`
`gaming. To simultaneously hold that these products are outside the relevant mar-
`
`ket yet meaningfully reduce switching costs is pure nonsense. The holdings cannot
`
`coexist as a matter of law and economics.
`
`B.
`
`The District Court Did Not Properly Assess Apple’s Conduct as It
`Relates to the Source of Apple’s Market Power
`
`Where high information and switching costs lock consumers into an after-
`
`market, the lock-in can be illegally exploited in the aftermarket in at least two key
`
`ways that Epic raises: (1) leveraging and (2) raising entry barriers. First, where
`
`lock-in creates market power in an aftermarket, a firm can use its power in the af-
`
`termarket as a means to secure market power in a second aftermarket. That is lev-
`
`eraging. Epic alleges that Apple did so by exploiting customers locked into an
`
`app-distribution aftermarket to force them to use Apple’s IAP services.
`
`Second, a company can monopolize by taking steps to strengthen or deepen
`
`the existing lock-in of its customers in any or all of its aftermarkets. Anticompeti-
`
`tive acts that increase lock-in raise entry barriers. Epic alleges that Apple
`
`
`
`10
`
`

`

`Case: 21-16506, 01/27/2022, ID: 12353961, DktEntry: 57, Page 17 of 39
`
`
`
`increased lock-in of aftermarket App Store and IAP customers by anticompeti-
`
`tively increasing or maintaining information and switching costs.
`
`These two methods of exploiting lock-in can be analyzed differently depend-
`
`ing on the source of market power in the aftermarket. In a tying or monopoly lever-
`
`aging case like Kodak, the source of market power in the market being leveraged
`
`(e.g., the tying market) is irrelevant. The anticompetitive conduct is the leveraging
`
`of that monopoly in one (after)market into monopoly power in another (after)mar-
`
`ket (e.g., leveraging parts to get power in service). Monopoly leveraging is illegal
`
`and anticompetitive even if the monopoly power being leveraged is completely
`
`lawful.
`
`Accordingly, the fact that the original power comes from producing a supe-
`
`rior product that customers love, Slip op. at 50-51 (customer satisfaction), or from
`
`some other legal conduct, Slip op. at 48 (“not necessarily nefarious”), does not ex-
`
`cuse leveraging that market power into another market where competition would
`
`otherwise exist. Kodak, 504 U.S. at 479 n.29 (“The Court has held many times
`
`that power gained through some natural and legal advantage such as a patent, cop-
`
`yright, or business acumen can give rise to liability if ‘a seller exploits his domi-
`
`nant position in one market to expand his empire into the next.’”) (quoting Times-
`
`Picayune Publishing Co. v. United States, 345 U.S. 594, 611 (1953)); Image Tech.
`
`Servs. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 125 F.3d 1195, 1216 (9th Cir. 1997) (“Section 2 of
`
`
`
`11
`
`

`

`Case: 21-16506, 01/27/2022, ID: 12353961, DktEntry: 57, Page 18 of 39
`
`
`
`the Sherman Act condemns exclusionary conduct that extends natural monopolies
`
`into separate markets.”).
`
`On the other hand, when it comes to increasing lock-in to raise entry barri-
`
`ers, the source of the information and switching costs that create lock-in does mat-
`
`ter. When lock-in is increased, the allegation in a monopolization case is that the
`
`defendant took actions with the purpose and design to acquire, enhance or maintain
`
`monopoly power. Merely possessing market or monopoly power is not illegal, and
`
`firms with monopoly power are permitted and encouraged to compete like any oth-
`
`ers, including in an aftermarket. Only the acquisition or maintenance of monopoly
`
`power (or attempts) by means other than competition on the merits is illegal. Thus,
`
`where the source of market power is lock-in created by switching and information
`
`costs, the question of whether those costs have been raised or maintained by un-
`
`lawful actions of the defendant, or instead by competition on the merits, is at the
`
`heart of the inquiry.
`
`In undertaking that inquiry, though, courts must bear in mind that market
`
`power arising from sources other than defendants allegedly anticompetitive actions
`
`is irrelevant. Monopolistic conduct that raises entry barriers almost always arises
`
`in a context where the defendant has some degree of legitimate and legal market
`
`power, be it from a first-mover advantage, a high-quality product, or for structural
`
`reasons. The source of that market power is generally not relevant, because
`
`
`
`12
`
`

`

`Case: 21-16506, 01/27/2022, ID: 12353961, DktEntry: 57, Page 19 of 39
`
`
`
`monopolization is concerned not with the background market power of the defend-
`
`ant, but with the defendant’s allegedly illegal actions to increase or maintain that
`
`market power. Salop, at 4 (“Market definition and market power should be evalu-
`
`ated in the context of the alleged anticompetitive conduct and effect….”).
`
`So too here. Apple has a certain degree of lawfully earned market power
`
`from the fact that the iPhone is a unique product that consumers like and is pro-
`
`tected from competition by intellectual property rights. As discussed above, that
`
`market power relates to the foremarket. Likewise, aftermarkets for the App Store
`
`and in-app payment systems exist because of switching and information costs that
`
`prevent foremarket competition from effectively cabining the exercise of market
`
`power in these aftermarkets.
`
`All of this is immaterial to Epic’s monopolization claims. It is not the exist-
`
`ence of aftermarkets where Apple has market power that Epic alleges constitutes
`
`illegal monopolization. It is that Apple took steps to increase or maintain the in-
`
`formation and switching costs, and thus its power in these aftermarkets, that Epic
`
`alleges is illegal.
`
`Properly understood against the context of Epic’s allegations, it is clear that
`
`the district court misunderstood the significance of its finding that people are reluc-
`
`tant to switch away from the iPhone in response to Apple’s conduct in the app dis-
`
`tribution and in-app payment markets because of “overall satisfaction with existing
`
`
`
`13
`
`

`

`Case: 21-16506, 01/27/2022, ID: 12353961, DktEntry: 57, Page 20 of 39
`
`
`
`devices.” Slip op. at 51. It is because consumers are overall satisfied with Apple’s
`
`iPhone and iOS that Apple’s monopolization scheme was effective. For consum-
`
`ers who are “overall happy with their devices,” switching is a high cost, indeed.
`
`At its core, Epic’s monopolization claim is that Apple engaged in conduct to
`
`maintain or increase its market power in app distribution and in-app payment mar-
`
`kets by increasing or maintaining the high switching and information costs that
`
`create lock-in. How? By imposing contractual restrictions on developers that (a)
`
`prevented them from reducing information costs by the use of links and other
`
`forms of communication through their apps and (b) prevented them from reducing
`
`the costs of switching away from Apple’s App Store or iOS IAP by allowing cus-
`
`tomers to keep the iPhone and iOS they like while blocking them from accessing
`
`rival app stores or in-app payment methods. That consumers genuinely like the
`
`overall iPhone product is exactly what makes the second restriction so effective; it
`
`means the cost of switching away from the App Store or iOS IAP is the cost of giv-
`
`ing up the iPhone altogether. See Phillip Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust
`
`Law ¶ 564 (4th and 5th eds. 2013-2020) (markups in aftermarkets are particularly
`
`effective when small relative to the overall cost of the product).
`
`C. A Common Error Underlies the District Court’s Failure to Recog-
`nize Distinct Markets in at Least Two Instances
`
`Proceeding from first principles rooted in economics also helps identify a
`
`common error behind the district court’s failure to recognize distinct markets in at
`
`
`
`14
`
`

`

`Case: 21-16506, 01/27/2022, ID: 12353961, DktEntry: 57, Page 21 of 39
`
`
`
`least two instances. The district court rejected plaintiffs’ claim that a foremarket
`
`for mobile operating systems exists that is distinct from the market for
`
`smartphones. Slip op. at 45 (“[I]t is illogical to argue that there is a market for
`
`something that is not licensed or sold to anyone. Competition exists for
`
`smartphones which are more than just operating systems.”). Accordingly, it con-
`
`cluded there could be no aftermarkets for the App Store and iOS IAP.4 Slip op. at
`
`45–46 (“Given the Court’s rejection of the foremarket theory, the aftermarket the-
`
`ory fails as it is tethered to the foremarket.”). The district court also rejected
`
`Epic’s claim that in-app payment processing and app-distribution are distinct prod-
`
`uct markets. Slip op. at 65–67 (finding “[t]he [IAP] system is not something that is
`
`bought or sold” and, therefore, not “a separate and distinct product” from the App
`
`Store). As a result, it held the App Store and IAP could not be anticompetitively
`
`tied together. Both of these holdings are rooted in a common and fundamental er-
`
`ror: assuming that the way markets currently operate reflects the way competitive
`
`markets would operate. This same fundamental error underlies the infamous “cel-
`
`lophane fallacy” and many other intellectual traps for the unwary in antitrust law.
`
`
`4 There is no logical reason why the conclusion that there can be no aftermarket
`must follow from the district court’s conclusion that no separate market for mobile
`operating systems exists. If the district court concluded that mobile operat

This document is available on Docket Alarm but you must sign up to view it.


Or .

Accessing this document will incur an additional charge of $.

After purchase, you can access this document again without charge.

Accept $ Charge
throbber

Still Working On It

This document is taking longer than usual to download. This can happen if we need to contact the court directly to obtain the document and their servers are running slowly.

Give it another minute or two to complete, and then try the refresh button.

throbber

A few More Minutes ... Still Working

It can take up to 5 minutes for us to download a document if the court servers are running slowly.

Thank you for your continued patience.

This document could not be displayed.

We could not find this document within its docket. Please go back to the docket page and check the link. If that does not work, go back to the docket and refresh it to pull the newest information.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

You need a Paid Account to view this document. Click here to change your account type.

Your account does not support viewing this document.

Set your membership status to view this document.

With a Docket Alarm membership, you'll get a whole lot more, including:

  • Up-to-date information for this case.
  • Email alerts whenever there is an update.
  • Full text search for other cases.
  • Get email alerts whenever a new case matches your search.

Become a Member

One Moment Please

The filing “” is large (MB) and is being downloaded.

Please refresh this page in a few minutes to see if the filing has been downloaded. The filing will also be emailed to you when the download completes.

Your document is on its way!

If you do not receive the document in five minutes, contact support at support@docketalarm.com.

Sealed Document

We are unable to display this document, it may be under a court ordered seal.

If you have proper credentials to access the file, you may proceed directly to the court's system using your government issued username and password.


Access Government Site

We are redirecting you
to a mobile optimized page.





Document Unreadable or Corrupt

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket

We are unable to display this document.

Refresh this Document
Go to the Docket